Optimal Investment and Risk Control Strategy for an Insurer under the Framework of Expected Logarithmic Utility ()
Received 2 March 2016; accepted 23 April 2016; published 26 April 2016

1. Introduction
In the past two decades, more and more attention has been paid to the problem of optimal investment in financial markets for an insurer. Indeed, this is a very important portfolio selection problem for the insurer from a point of finance theory. Merton (1969) [1] first used stochastic control theory to solve consumption and investment problem in framework of continuous financial market. Based on the Merton’s work, Zhou and Yin (2004) [2] , and Sotomayor and Cadenillas (2009) [3] considered consumption/investment problem in a financial market with regime switching. Under the mean-variance criterion and the utility maximization criterion, respectively, they obtained explicit solutions. In view of an external risk which can be insured against by purchasing insurance policy into Merton’s framework, Moore and Young (2006) [4] cooperated and studied optimal consumption, investment and insurance problem. Following Moore and Young (2006) [4] , Perera (2010) [5] resolved the same problem in a more general Levy market. Along the same work, many researchers applied an uncontrollable risk process to Merton’s model, such as Yang and Zhang (2005) [6] . They considered stochastic control problem for optimal investment strategy without consumption under a certain criteria.
For an insurer, since reinsurance is an important tool to manage its risk exposure, optimal reinsurance problem should be considered carefully. This issue implies that the insurer has to select reinsurance payout for certain financial objectives. The classical model for risk in the insurance literatures is Cramer-Lundberg model, which uses a compound Poisson process to measure risk. Based on the limiting process of compound Poisson process, Taksar (2000) [7] wrote the paper about optimal risk and dividend distribution control. Following his same vein, recent researches started to model the risk by diffusion process or a jump-diffusion process; see, e.g. Wang (2007) [8] and Zou (2014) [9] . Considering both proportional reinsurance and step-loss reinsurance, Kaluszka (2001) [10] researched optimal reinsurance in discrete time under the mea-variance criterion. What’s more, recent generalizations in modeling optimal reinsurance process include incorporating regime switching, and interest rate risk and inflation risk; see Zhuo et al. (2013) [11] Guan and Liang (2014) [12] respectively.
In this paper, the model and optimization problem are different from others. Firstly, it is not total wealth of insurer invested, but a part of wealth invested. So in this model, we can obtain the optimal property of the total wealth. Secondly, different from Merton’s work, we use a jump-diffusion process to model an insurer’s risk. Lastly, we regulate the insurer’s risk by controlling the number of polices.
This paper is organized as follow. In Section 2, we formulate investment and risk control problem and describe the financial model and risk process model. The explicit solution of optimal investment and risk control strategy for logarithmic utility is derived in Section 3. In Section 4, we conduct a sensitive analysis. Conclusions of the research are reached in Section 5.
2. The Financial Model and the Risk Process Model
Suppose that there are two assets for investment in the financial market. One is a riskless asset with price process
and the other is a risky asset with price process
. The dynamic of
and
are give by
(2.1)
respectively, where
and
are positive bounded functions and
is a standard Brownian motion. The initial conditions are
and 
For an insurer, most of its incomes come from writing insurance policies, and we denote the total outstanding number of policies at time t by
. To simplify our analysis, we assume that the insurer’s average premium for per policy is p, so the total incomes from selling insurance policies over the time period
is given by 
A classical risk model for claims is compound Poisson model, in which the claim for per policy is given by
where
is a series of independent and identically distributed random variables, and
is a Poisson process independent of
. If the mean of
and the intensity of
are finite, such compound Poisson process is a Levy process with finite Levy measure. According to Oksendal and Sulem (2005, Theorem 1.7) [13] , a Levy process can be decomposed into three components, a linear drift part, a Brownian motion part and a pure jump part. Based on this theorem, we suppose the insurer’s risk for per policy is given by
(2.2)
where
is a standard Brownian motion and N is a Poisson process defined on the given filtered space, respectively. We assume that
are all positive constants. As Stein (2012) [14] considered, we assume
(2.3)
where
and
is another standard Brownian motion, independent of
. We also suppose that the Poisson process N has a constant intensity
, and is independent of both
and
.
For an insurer, it should be noted that it is impossible for an insurer to invest its total wealth. At time t, we denote
as a part of the insurance wealth invested. Under this consideration, we let
and
be the amount invested in the risky asset and the total liabilities respectively. For a strategy
the terminal wealth process
is driven by the following SDE:
(2.4)
with initial wealth ![]()
Following Stein (2012, chapter 6) [14] , we define the liability radio of liabilities over surplus as
. We denote
as the total proportion of wealth invested,
as the proportion of wealth invested in the risky asset at time t. Then for a control
, we have
. Then we can rewrite SDE (2.4) as
(2.5)
with initial wealth
.
In this model, as Zou (2014) [9] considered, to compensate extra risk by extra return, the coefficients must satisfy the following conditions:
and
.
Define the criterion function as
, where
is the terminal time, and
is a
conditional expectation under probability measure P given
. The utility function U is assumed to be a strictly increasing and concave. In this paper, the choice for the utility function in economics and finance is
. We denote
as the set of all admissible controls with initial wealth
. In Section 3, we give the formal definition of
when
and choose either u or
to be a control. The value function is defined by
(2.6)
where u will be changed accordingly if the control we choose is
.
3. The Analysis for ![]()
Firstly formulate the stochastic control problem. The problem in this model is to select an admissible control
(or
) that attains the value function
. The control
(or
) is called an optimal control or an optimal policy. We choose u as an admissible control and for every
is progressively measurable and
satisfies the following conditions,
. (3.1)
Furthermore, we assume
while
to avoid the possibility of bankruptcy at jumps.
As we know that for
, the SDE (2.5) satisfies the linear growth condition and Lipschitz continuity condition, thus by Theorem 1.19 in Oksendal and Sulem (2005) [13] , there exists a unique solution
such
that
for all ![]()
Applying Ito’s formula to
, we can obtain that
(3.2)
where
is the compensated Poisson process of N and is a martingale under P. Let
(3.3)
Proposition 3.1. The associated optimal terminal wealth
is strictly positive with probability 1 under optimal control
.
Proof. According to (2.5) and the Doleans-Dade exponential formula, we have that
(3.4)
From (3.4), to prove
with probability 1, we just need to prove
with probabili-
ty 1. For any
,
and
or 0, we have
So we can obtain that
. This implies that
with probability 1.
Next, we will use the martingale method to get an optimal control for the SDE (2.5). To begin with, we give two important Lemmas. Lemma 3.1 gives the condition that optimal control must satisfy while Lemma 3.2 is a generalized version of martingale representation theorem.
Lemma 3.1. (Wang (2007) [8] ) If there exists a control
such that
is con-
stant over all admissible controls, then
is optimal control.
Lemma 3.2. (Wang (2007) [8] ) There exists a predicable process
for any P-martingale Z such that for all ![]()
for all
. (3.5)
Now for the value function
we obtain optimal control by 3 steps.
Step 1: Conjecture candidates for optimal control
.
Following the definition in Zou (2014) [9] , we also define that
and
(3.6)
for any stopping time
almost surely. According to the Proposition 3.1, the process Z is a strictly positive and square-integral martingale under P with
, for all
. Define a new measure Q by
.
From the SDE (2.4), we have
(3.7)
From the above expression of X and Lemma 3.1, for all admissible strategies, we have
(3.8)
is constant.
Define
. Since Z is a P-martingale, so is C.
According to Lemma 3.2, there exists a predictable process
such that
(3.9)
From the Doleans-Dade exponential formula, we can obtain that
(3.10)
Through Girsanov’s Theorem,
is a Brownian motion under Q and
is a martingale under Q.
For a stopping time
let
, that is
and
,which is an admissible
control. By substituting this control into (3.8), we have
is a constant for all
which implies that
is a Q-martingale.
So
must satisfy the equation that
(3.11)
Let
and
. By a similar way as above, we have
(3.12)
is a Q-martingale, which in turn yields that
(3.13)
From the SDE (2.5), we can derive to
,
(3.14)
Comparing the
and
terms in (3.10) with (3.14), we obtain that
(3.15)
By substituting (3.15) into (3.11) and (3.13), we have that
(3.16)
(3.17)
which the coefficients define as
(3.18)
With the conditions above, solve the Equation (3.17) to get
. Since
,
, (3.19)
where ![]()
According to the (3.19), we can derive
with (3.16).
Then we choose that
and
to get
. Similarly, by substituting this control into (3.8), we have
(3.20)
so we can have
by the Equation (3.20).
Step 2: Verify that ZT defined by (3.10) is consistent with its definition, for
given in (3.15) and
defined by (3.16), (3.17) and (3.20).
First rewrite (3.14) as
(3.21)
where
(3.22)
Then substituting (3.15) back into (3.10), we can obtain
where
(3.23)
is constant.
According to the (3.6), Z is a P-martingale and
, then
. Therefore,
(3.24)
so Z given by (3.10) with
provided by (3.15) is the same as the definition in (3.6).
Step 3: Prove that
satisfies the Lemma 3.1.
For any
, we give a definition for a new process
as follows
(3.25)
From the Equation (3.13), the above
issue will be 0, and then the process
is a local martingale. As
is a deterministic and bounded, Z is a square-integral martingale under P, that is to say
. Meantime, for all
, we can obtain that
, so is
. Therefore, we can derive
, (3.26)
which make possible for us to conclude that the family
is uniformly integral under Q for any stopping time
. Thus
is indeed a martingale under Q with
for any
. So we can prove that Lemma 3.1 is satisfied. Therefore, we have an optimal control for the function
.
4. Sensitive Analysis
In this part, we analyze the influence of the market parameters on the optimal control. To simplify the analysis, we assume that the coefficients are constant in the financial market and the parameters are given in Table 1 which was also used in Zou (2014) [9] . From Table 1, we know that the variables
and
are not fixed, so we shall analyze the impact of
and
on the optimal control.
Firstly, we fix
to research the influence of
. The optimal control of
are given by (3.16), (3.17), (3.20), respectively. We draw the graph of optimal control with different values of
in Figure 1. From Figure 1, we can know that optimal investment proportion in the securities
is an increasing function of
, and the optimal liability ratio
is like a convex function of
. Besides, the optimal total proportion of wealth invested
is decreasing when
and then increasing. What’s more, the graph shows that
. The reason for this behavior comes from the equations of R and
in (2.2). For our parameters, there is much uncertainty in the insurance market when
belongs to the interval
, and hence
takes a minimum value in that interval. While
takes value near 0 there is little uncertainty, so
takes a maximum value. Since
is calculated from the equation (3.16),
also takes a maximum value when
takes value near 0.
Secondly, we fix
to analyze the impact of
. Consider
which include the previous situation
. We have a graph of optimal control with different value of
in Figure 2. Figure 2 shows that the optimal investment proportion in the securities
is an increasing function of
, and the optimal total proportion of wealth invested
and the optimal liability ratio
are both decreasing function of
. This situation is supported by the economic interpretation of
. In this model, the greater
, the more risk for insurers. So, when
rises, a risk averse insurer reduces its optimal liability ratio. As the optimal investment expressions (3.17), we know that when
raises,
increases as well. Besides, according to the optimal total proportion of wealth invested
and the optimal liability ratio
expressions (3.20) and (3.17) respectively, we know that when
rises,
and
decreases however.
![]()
Figure 1. Impact of
on the optimal control.
![]()
Figure 2. Impact of
on the optimal control.
5. Conclusions
In our model, the insurer’s risk process obeys a jump-diffusion process, and it is not total its capital to invest but a part of wealth to invest in financial market. Besides, we consider that an insurer wants to maximize its expected utility of terminal wealth by selecting optimal control. According to the sensitive analysis, we know that the optimal total proportion of wealth invested
and the optimal liability ratio
are convex functions of
, but they are both decreasing functions of
. The optimal investment proportion in the securities or derivatives
is an increasing function for both
and
, and
. Furthermore, we find that the higher risk insurers get, the lower liability ratio insurers select.
The limitation in this paper is that the liability is an average for per policy, which conflicts with the fact that the premium for per policy changes all the time for different insurance. Therefore we can research the liability described with a linear function in the model. Besides, the model proposed in the paper can be further explored in another ways as well, something we plan to do in future work.
Acknowledgments
The author thanks to the editor and the reviewers for their thoughtful comments that help the author improve a prior version of this article.