The Impact of International Trade on Income Inequality in the SADC Region

Abstract

This study examines the influence of international trade on income inequality within the Southern African Development Community (SADC) by employing the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) Panel Fixed Effects and the Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS) Panel Instrumental Variable Approach. The findings indicate an inverse correlation between international trade and income inequality, suggesting that trade can contribute to equitable income distribution in the SADC region. However, the study also reveals that the impact of trade on inequality varies across income groups, with trade generally increasing inequality in countries outside the least developed nations. The results further highlight the role of resource endowment in shaping income inequality, showing that trade tends to increase inequalities in resource-rich economies due to the uneven distribution of economic gains. These findings challenge the universality of conventional trade theories, particularly the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, in the context of the SADC region. The study contributes to the growing body of literature by providing region-specific insights and recommending targeted policy interventions to ensure that trade benefits are more equitably distributed.

Share and Cite:

Chigwenembe, N. and Zheng, W. (2025) The Impact of International Trade on Income Inequality in the SADC Region. Modern Economy, 16, 399-418. doi: 10.4236/me.2025.163019.

1. Introduction

International trade has historically been a fundamental driver of economic growth, yet its role in shaping income inequality remains contentious (Anderson, 2005; Borrs & Knauth, 2021; Harrison et al., 2011; Lee & Wie, 2015; Nigai, 2022). This debate is particularly pronounced in Africa, which continues to experience some of the highest levels of inequality and absolute poverty worldwide (Kolawole, 2016). Within the Southern African Development Community (SADC), income inequality persists despite decades of trade liberalization, raising concerns about whether trade has contributed to or mitigated disparities in wealth distribution (Jauch, 2011; Martin, 2022).

According to traditional trade theories, particularly the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, trade should reduce inequality in developing economies by benefiting their abundant factor typically unskilled labor (Lin & Fu, 2016). However, SADC countries show diverse factor endowments. While trade reduces inequality in labor-abundant nations like Malawi and Mozambique by increasing low-skilled employment (Jaumotte et al., 2008), it also increases inequality in resource-rich economies like Botswana and Angola, where resource rents are highly concentrated among elites (Cerdeiro & Komaromi, 2021). This divergence highlights the need for country-specific trade policies rather than relying solely on conventional trade theories.

While extensive research has explored the relationship between trade and inequality, much of this work has focused on global or cross-regional analyses, with limited emphasis on Africa, and particularly the SADC region. Most existing studies fail to account for the role of resource endowment in shaping income distribution within trade-dependent economies. This study addresses these gaps by hypothesizing that international trade reduces income inequality in resource-poor SADC countries but increases it in resource-rich nations due to wealth concentration among elites.

This study makes three key contributions to the literature on trade and inequality. First, it provides empirical evidence specific to the SADC region, offering insights that challenge the applicability of traditional trade theories such as the Stolper-Samuelson theorem in resource-rich developing economies. Secondly, by employing an instrumental variable approach, it strengthens causal inferences regarding trade’s impact on inequality, addressing endogeneity concerns that have often undermined previous studies. Third, the study highlights the importance of tailored policy interventions, advocating for differentiated trade policies that consider income levels and resource distribution within the region.

The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature, Section 3 outlines the methodology, Section 4 presents and discusses the results, and Section 5 concludes with policy recommendations.

2. Literature Review

2.1. International Trade on Income Inequality-Factor Endowment

International trade theory highlights factor endowment as a key determinant of trade’s impact on income inequality. In labor-abundant developing countries, trade is expected to reduce inequality by boosting employment for low-skilled workers, whereas in capital- and skill-abundant nations, trade tends to widen income disparities by increasing returns to these factors (Calderón et al., 2020; de Melo et al., 2011).

However, in resource-rich countries, resource rents often concentrate among elites, increasing inequality (Basu & Chau, 2018). In contrast, resource-poor countries tend to experience more equitable outcomes from trade, as it promotes employment and inclusive growth (Jacoby, 2020; Roser & Cuaresma, 2016). SADC countries with mixed endowments do not neatly fit this framework. South Africa and Namibia, for example, exhibit both labor- and capital-intensive industries, leading to ambiguous trade-inequality relationships (Basu & Chau, 2018).

While the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem posits that trade reduces inequality in labor-abundant countries, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem often fails in resource-rich SADC nations due to the concentrated benefits of resource wealth (Munir & Bukhari, 2020). This study investigates how resource endowments mediate trade’s effects on inequality in the SADC region.

2.2. Effects of International Trade on Income Inequality

Income inequality in the Southern African Development Community is shaped by globalization, technological advancements, and international trade (Acemoglu, 2003; Goldberg & Pavcnik, 2007; Jaumotte et al., 2008). Trade liberalization influences inequality differently across SADC countries, depending on their economic structures and factor endowments. In labor-abundant economies, lowering trade barriers can enhance employment and wages for low-skilled workers, leading to a reduction in income inequality (Ganaie et al., 2018; Jonathan Gimba et al., 2021). However, in resource-rich countries, trade openness tends to reinforce disparities, as wealth from natural resource exports is often concentrated among political and economic elites, leaving low-income groups with limited gains (Cerdeiro & Komaromi, 2021; Silva, 2007).

The effect of international trade on inequality also varies based on the nature of exports and imports. Many SADC countries rely heavily on primary commodity exports, such as minerals, oil, and agricultural products, which tend to generate concentrated profits rather than widespread economic benefits (Baldwin, 2016; Milanovic, 2016). The resource sector is capital-intensive, employing a small fraction of the workforce, which limits the trickle-down effect to lower-income groups (Mayer & Wood, 2001). This dynamic leads to the so-called resource curse, where natural wealth exacerbates inequality rather than promoting inclusive development (Ross, 2001; Collier & Goderis, 2012).

On the import side, trade liberalization often leads to a surge in foreign-manufactured goods, which can benefit low-income consumers through reduced prices but may also negatively impact domestic industries and employment (Topalova, 2010; Pavcnik, 2017). In some SADC countries, increased imports of manufactured goods have displaced local industries that rely on semi-skilled labor, further widening income disparities (McMillan & Rodrik, 2011).

Foreign direct investment (FDI), facilitated by trade liberalization, plays a crucial role in shaping inequality within SADC economies. Some studies suggest that FDI, particularly in labor-intensive sectors such as manufacturing and services, can reduce inequality by creating jobs and improving wages for lower-income workers (Choi, 2006; Dollar & Kraay, 2004). However, other findings indicate that FDI inflows are often directed toward capital-intensive industries, which primarily benefit higher-skilled workers and multinational corporations, exacerbating wage gaps (Herzer & Nunnenkamp, 2013; Jaumotte et al., 2008).

Trade policies, including tariff structures, regional trade agreements, and export promotion strategies, also influence inequality outcomes. Some SADC countries have pursued industrialization policies aimed at diversifying exports beyond primary commodities to promote more equitable economic growth (Te Velde, 2017; UNCTAD, 2020). However, the success of such policies depends on complementary measures, such as investment in education, infrastructure, and social protection programs, to ensure broader participation in trade-related economic gains (Goldberg & Pavcnik, 2016).

2.3. Literature Gap and Contribution

While previous studies have examined the relationship between trade liberalization and income inequality in developing economies (Goldberg & Pavcnik, 2007; Milanovic, 2016; Jaumotte et al., 2008), there remains a limited body of research focusing specifically on the SADC region. Existing literature often generalizes the effects of trade on inequality across Africa or broader developing regions without accounting for the unique economic structures and policy environments of SADC nations.

Furthermore, while many studies highlight the resource curse and its implications for inequality (Collier & Goderis, 2012; Ross, 2001), few of them have provided empirical analysis linking trade liberalization, export dependency, and sectoral employment patterns in the SADC context. Most research on trade and inequality in the region tends to focus on country-level aggregate measures, overlooking the distributional effects across different income groups, sectors, and geographic regions.

This paper fills this gap by offering a SADC-specific analysis of how trade openness affects income distribution, distinguishing between the impacts of export structures, import penetration, and FDI inflows. By incorporating cross-country panel data evidence, this study provides new insights into the trade-inequality relationship in the SADC region.

3. Methodology

3.1. Data

This study examines the impact of international trade on income inequality in the Southern African Development Community (SADC) region, covering a period of 33 years (1990-2023). The dataset integrates macroeconomic data from multiple sources, including the World Development Indicators (World Bank), the Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID v9.3), the World Income Inequality Database (WIID), the Economic Commission for Africa Database, and National Statistics Offices. The SADC region consists of 16 member countries: Angola, Botswana, Comoros, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Eswatini, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Seychelles, South Africa, Tanzania, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.

Variable Description

Dependent Variable: Income inequality is measured using the Gini index, sourced from the WIID and SWIID (v9.3). The study employs the Gini index due to its widespread use and cross-country comparability (Solt, 2020). However, alternative measures such as the Palma ratio and Theil index were considered. The Palma ratio provides insights into inequality by focusing on disparities between the richest 10% and poorest 40% (Cobham & Sumner, 2013). The Theil index, while useful in capturing inequality decomposition, is less widely available for SADC countries.

Independent Variable: International trade, the primary explanatory variable, is measured as the sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP. Data are sourced from the World Development Indicators (2024) and the Economic Commission for Africa (2024). For Malawi, data were obtained from the National Statistics Office due to availability issues. This measure captures the dual effects of trade liberalization, which may reduce or exacerbate inequality depending on economic structure (Lin & Fu, 2016; Mahesh, 2016).

Control Variables: To address confounding factors, the following variables are including Natural Resources Measured as resource rents (% of GDP), to account for the role of resource dependence in economic outcomes. Resource wealth can increase inequality by concentrating wealth among elites. GDP Per Capita Controls for income distribution effects at different income levels (Dorn et al., 2021) Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) is measured as FDI inflows (% of GDP), capturing the globalization-inequality nexus (Felbermayr et al., 2011). Human Development Index (HDI): Used as a proxy for productivity and development, as HDI correlates with income inequality (Odusola et al., 2017). Household Consumption Expenditure: Reflects residents’ expenditures, which are positively linked to income inequality (Zakaria & Fida, 2016). Population: Included to capture demographic influences on trade and inequality. Geographical Distribution: Accounts for spatial differences across the SADC region.

Robustness Check Variables: Additional controls include ICT exports (% of GDP) and government final consumption expenditure (% of GDP). ICT exports proxy for technological factors, while government expenditure accounts for redistributive policies affecting income inequality (Dorn et al., 2021; Jaumotte et al., 2008).

3.2. Model Specification

3.2.1. Panel Fixed Effects

The baseline panel model for this research is estimated by ordinary least square (OLS) adopted from (Dorn et al., 2021). In this research, countries are described by i and annual periods by t, which differs from (Dorn et al., 2021) in which they group t into five-year periods. Therefore, our baseline line model is as follows:

Gin i i,t =β×Trad e i,t +Θ0× X i,t + v i + v t + ε i,t (3.1)

Gin i i,t describing the measure of income inequality of a country (i) in a period (t). In this research, the explanatory variable is Trad e i,t describing the ratio of imports and exports of the country (i) in a period (t). X i,t Vector of control variables, including GDP per capita, HDI, household consumption expenditure, and FDI. v i intends to describe the country’s fixed effects, v t describes the fixed period effects, and ε i,t It is the error term. Standard errors are clustered by country to account for heteroscedasticity and serial correlation, following Dorn et al. (2021).

3.2.2. Panel Instrumental Variable Approach (2SLS)

To address potential endogeneity in the relationship between trade and income inequality, a two-stage least squares (2SLS) approach is employed. Endogeneity may arise due to omitted variables or reverse causality (Dorn et al., 2021). The 2SLS model consists of the following stages:

First Stage: Trad e i,t = β 0 + β 1 ARE A i,t + β 2 PO P i,t + β 3 X i,t + u it + ε it (3.2)

where AREA and POP represent geographical size and population, respectively.

Second Stage: Uses predicted trade values to estimate their effect on inequality:

Gin i i,t =α+ β 1 Trad e i,t + β 2 X i,t + u it + ε it (3.3)

Third Stage: Introduces resource endowment to explore differential effects for resource-rich and resource-poor countries:

Gin i i,t = β 0 + β 1 Trad e i,t + β 2 X i,t + β 3 Trad e Endowment,t + u i + u t + ε it (3.4)

3.2.3. Construction of Instruments

The study constructs instruments using geographical variables (area and population) based on their exogenous relationship with trade. Larger areas and populations are negatively correlated with trade openness due to increased domestic market size (Aradhyula et al., 2007). These instruments are valid under the exclusion restriction, which assumes that geographical factors influence income inequality only through trade.

4. Results

4.1. Summary Statistics

This section presents key descriptive statistics highlighting economic and structural diversity across the SADC region. The Gini index, measuring income inequality before taxes and transfers, has a mean of 50.2%, ranging from 37.4% to 65.4%, indicating high inequality levels. The Palma ratio further emphasizes income disparities, with a mean of 10.57%. International trade, measured as the sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP, varies widely, with an average of 85% and a maximum of 217.2%. Natural resource rents, a proxy for resource wealth, range from near zero to 55.8%, with a mean of 7.75%, reflecting uneven resource distribution across countries.

Economic indicators reveal that GDP per capita averages $1.78 (ranging from -$6.1 to $8.4), placing most countries in the low- or lower-middle-income category. Human Development Index (HDI) values reinforce low development levels, while FDI inflows exhibit high variance, reflecting systemic barriers to investment. Household consumption expenditure also varies significantly across countries. These statistics underscore the region’s heterogeneity, necessitating tailored policy approaches (Table 1).

Table 1. Descriptive statistics.

Variable

Definition

Obs

Mean

Std. dev.

Min

Max

Gini Index

The measure of Income Inequality before tax and transfers

429

50.2105

7.60145

37.4

65.4

Palma Ratio

The measure of the Income share of the top 10% divided by bottom 40%

489

10.5774

5.13372

4.39205

24.85759

International Trade

The measure of Exports/Imports % of GDP

480

85.069

42.5941

20.4309

217.2914

Natural Resources

Natural Resource Rents % of GDP

492

7.75536

9.52045

0.00117

55.87479

GDP Per Capita

The sum of gross value added by residents’ producers of the economy

512

178.148

734.648

−26.4118

4527.565

Human Development Ind.

The measure of expected productivity

452

1.78965

0.53899

0.449

2.938816

Foreign Direct Investment

Net inflows FDI % of GDP

496

3.63083

5.76797

−10.725

57.87738

Human Consumption Exp.

The measure of expenditure incurred by the household

448

8.39622

1.42074

5.06725

12.42137

Population

Total number of people in a country

450

60.1761

15.6016

36.46

87.8

Area

The countries area measured in Sq.km

496

10.9519

2.82449

2.70805

13.79658

Source: Author’s regression results, 2024.

4.2. Baseline Results (Gini Index)

Table 2 presents the baseline estimations of international trade’s effect on income inequality in the SADC region. The findings suggest that trade significantly impacts inequality in resource-rich countries, while the effect is negligible in resource-poor nations. These results support traditional trade theories, such as Heckscher-Ohlin and Stolper-Samuelson, which predict that trade benefits the abundant factor of production. However, the resource curse appears to limit trade’s inequality-reducing effects in resource-rich contexts.

Key control variables such as natural resources correlate positively with inequality, confirming that resource rents are often concentrated among elites. GDP per capita, household consumption, and FDI are also positively correlated with inequality, suggesting that economic growth does not necessarily lead to equitable income distribution. Larger populations and land areas tend to correlate negatively with inequality, indicating structural factors that promote economic opportunities.

Table 2. International trade and income inequality—baseline estimations (OLS and 2SLS).

OLS

2SLS

Full

Res.

Low-Res.

Full

Res.

Low-Res

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

International Trade (log)

0.790**

1.195**

0.0528

−2.458***

−5.094*

−0.964

(0.361)

(0.505)

(0.485)

(0.838)

(2.760)

(0.633)

Natural Resources

−0.0429***

−0.0345*

−0.114**

0.0237

0.0828

−0.102**

(0.0152)

(0.0186)

(0.0450)

(0.0211)

(0.0529)

(0.0441)

GDP Per Capita

0.0007***

−0.0389**

0.0005**

0.0005**

−0.0165

0.0006***

(0.0002)

(0.0193)

(0.0002)

(0.0002)

(0.0285)

(0.0002)

Human Development Index

0.601

0.876

−0.675

1.058*

2.155*

−0.358

(0.567)

(0.794)

(0.718)

(0.638)

(1.131)

(0.809)

Foreign Direct Investment

−0.0103

−0.00108

−0.0246

0.0670***

0.124**

−0.0405

(0.0154)

(0.0195)

(0.0320)

(0.0211)

(0.0515)

(0.0364)

Household Consumption Exp. (log)

0.385**

0.727***

0.201

0.0377

0.0018

0.0565

(0.159)

(0.247)

(0.208)

(0.164)

(0.267)

(0.230)

Population (log)

−5.097***

−4.072**

−13.88***

(1.477)

(1.931)

(2.824)

Area (log)

−7.160***

−11.12***

−4.655***

(1.323)

(2.546)

(1.446)

constant

146.4***

198.6***

150.7***

(15.80)

(33.32)

(16.03)

Fixed Effects

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Year FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Countries

15

8

7

15

8

7

No. Observations

365

196

169

365

196

169

R-Squared

0.165

0.180

0.388

−0.090

−0.581

0.207

Endogeneity Test

14.222

0.0002

Sargan Statistic Test

18.543

0.0000

To address endogeneity concerns, a two-stage least squares (2SLS) approach confirms the findings, reinforcing the role of resource endowment in shaping inequality outcomes (Figure 1, Table 2).

Figure 1. Non-Monotonic relationship of international trade and income inequality (Gini Index)-OLS.

The above graph illustrates the marginal effects of international trade on income inequality as a function of trade volume. The model using OLS panel fixed effects and clustered robust standard errors estimates the impact of international Trade on income inequality using Gini Index to measure income inequality. The points on the graph represent the marginal effects of a 1 percent increase in international trade on income inequality, according to the level of international trade indicated on the x-axis. The lines represent confidence intervals at 95 percent.

4.3. The Role of Income Levels in Trade-Inequality Nexus

The impact of international trade on income inequality in the SADC region varies significantly depending on a country’s income level. The analysis groups countries into upper-middle, lower-middle, and low-income categories, revealing distinct patterns. In upper-middle-income countries, trade generally reduces inequality, particularly through imports that lower consumer prices and increase access to goods. However, these effects weaken in the 2SLS estimations, indicating that the long-term benefits of trade on inequality reduction may be limited in these economies.

For lower-middle-income countries, the relationship between trade and inequality is less consistent. Structural challenges, such as limited economic diversification and unequal access to trade benefits, may explain the weaker outcomes observed in this group. While trade may contribute to reducing inequality in some instances, the results lack robustness across different specifications.

In contrast, low-income countries demonstrate the most robust and consistent inequality-reducing effects of trade. Both OLS and 2SLS estimations indicate that trade significantly reduces inequality, with exports playing a particularly strong role by creating employment opportunities and fostering economic growth among marginalized populations. Also, imports in low-income economies help lower the cost of essential goods, further contributing to inequality reduction.

These findings suggest the importance of targeted trade policies that account for structural differences among SADC countries. Policymakers should prioritize strategies that enhance labor-intensive industries in lower-income nations while ensuring that trade benefits are more evenly distributed across different economic segments.

The analysis also reveals distinct dynamics between exports and imports. While exports show mixed effects, sometimes positively associated with inequality, imports consistently reduce inequality across most specifications. This suggests that imports may have a more direct impact on improving welfare by lowering prices and increasing access to essential goods, particularly in lower-income contexts. The different results across the three income level groups shows that labor policies, governance structures, and institutional strength significantly influence trade’s impact on inequality (Goldberg & Pavcnik, 2007) (Table 3).

Table 3. Income levels in the SADC region-estimations.

Gini

Palma

Gini

Palma

Gini

Palma

Gini

Palma

Gini

Palma

Gini

Palma

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

(a) Full Sample

International Trade

0.790**

−2.87***

−2.4***

−6.57***

(0.361)

(0.862)

(0.838)

(1.708)

Exports

0.212

−3.07***

−1.67**

−3.99**

(0.289)

(0.640)

(0.802)

(1.618)

Imports

0.390

−1.84**

−3.36***

−8.96***

(0.301)

(0.711)

(0.908)

(1.855)

Countries

15

15

15

15

15

15

15

15

15

15

15

15

No. Observations

365

371

365

371

365

371

365

371

365

371

365

371

R-Squared

0.165

0.241

0.155

0.265

0.158

0.231

−0.090

0.105

−0.022

0.143

−0.260

−0.054

(b) Benchmark Sample

International Trade

1.747***

−3.67***

0.940

−15.5***

(0.309)

(0.962)

(1.163)

(2.723)

Exports

1.909***

−4.01***

4.434***

−17.8***

(0.318)

(0.954)

(1.494)

(4.237)

Imports

0.851***

−1.652*

−1.514*

−10.8***

(0.303)

(0.890)

(0.800)

(1.671)

Countries

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

No. Observations

154

144

154

144

154

144

154

144

154

144

154

144

R-Squared

0.657

0.692

0.664

0.699

0.601

0.667

0.529

0.254

0.434

0.073

0.330

0.340

(c) Upper Middle-Income

International Trade

1.290***

−0.985

−0.762

−39.8***

(0.382)

(1.396)

(1.093)

(11.85)

Exports

0.896**

−1.889

−0.867

−38.1***

(0.436)

−1.386

(1.243)

(12.26)

Imports

0.978***

−0.142

−0.610

−34.3***

(0.282)

(1.050)

(0.893)

(11.27)

Countries

4

4

4

4

4

4

4

4

4

4

4

4

No. Observations

105

90

105

90

105

90

105

90

105

90

105

90

R-Squared

0.698

0.797

0.676

0.801

0.700

0.796

0.597

−1.248

0.611

−1.050

0.590

−1.979

(d) Lower Middle-Income

International Trade

0.971

−0.759

−0.0461

0.260

(0.769)

(1.304)

(1.431)

(2.358)

Exports

−1.106*

−5.28***

3.095

−0.618

(0.587)

(0.887)

(1.983)

(2.810)

Imports

1.007

0.426

−1.024

0.494

(0.635)

(1.081)

(1.320)

(2.137)

Countries

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

6

No. Observations

142

146

142

146

142

146

142

146

142

146

142

146

R-Squared

0.143

0.104

0.155

0.292

0.149

0.102

0.088

0.098

−0.203

0.142

0.042

0.102

(e) Low Income

International Trade

0.567

1.372

−3.1***

−14.8***

(0.457)

(1.508)

(0.637)

(2.311)

Exports

1.291***

1.069

−2.98***

−14.0***

(0.286)

(0.968)

(0.904)

(2.864)

Imports

−0.457

0.587

−3.82***

−17.3***

(0.393)

(1.284)

(0.742)

(3.101)

Countries

5

5

5

5

5

5

5

5

5

5

5

5

No. Observations

118

135

118

135

118

135

118

135

118

135

118

135

R-Squared

0.510

0.568

0.583

0.569

0.509

0.565

0.146

0.143

−0.405

−0.333

0.132

−0.142

4.4. Heterogeneous Treatment Effects

The study further investigates how resource endowment influences trade’s impact on inequality. Using an interaction term between trade and resource endowment, the findings indicate that in resource-rich countries, international trade increases inequality, as resource rents remain concentrated among elites. In contrast, resource-poor countries experience more equitable outcomes. These findings emphasize the need for effective resource governance and economic diversification to prevent trade from reinforcing existing disparities (Table 4).

Table 4. Heterogeneous treatment effects.

1

2

3

4

International Trade (log)

0.158

−5.280***

18.19***

6.684***

(0.518)

(1.183)

(2.230)

(1.395)

International Trade*Endowment

1.048*

4.125***

2.801***

1.511***

(0.619)

(1.405)

(0.238)

(0.144)

Natural Resources

−0.0496***

0.0140

−0.643***

−0.252***

(0.0157)

(0.0368)

(0.0629)

(0.0404)

GDP Per Capita

0.0006***

−0.0027***

0.00132**

−8.97e−05

(0.0002)

(0.0005)

(0.0006)

(0.0003)

Human Development Index

0.607

−0.0702

−14.04***

−3.186***

(0.565)

(1.413)

(1.846)

(1.132)

Foreign Direct Investment

−0.0142

−0.0308

−0.610***

−0.172***

(0.0155)

(0.0360)

(0.0969)

(0.0621)

Household Consumption Exp. (log)

0.372**

0.0791

3.327***

−0.940**

(0.159)

(0.355)

(0.549)

(0.388)

Population (log)

−4.940***

−19.33***

(1.476)

(3.267)

Area (log)

−6.577***

−10.78***

(1.363)

(3.109)

constant

139.5***

227.1***

−29.63***

−4.589

(16.27)

(36.67)

(10.28)

(6.704)

Fixed Effects

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Year FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Countries

15

15

15

15

No. Observations

368

371

368

371

R-Squared

0.172

0.259

0.047

0.252

4.5. Robustness Check

Several robustness checks confirm the validity of the findings. First, substituting the Gini index with the Palma ratio yields consistent results, demonstrating that trade reduces inequality in resource-poor economies while increasing it in resource-rich ones. Second, including ICT exports as a proxy for technological development reveals that technology does not significantly alter the relationship between trade and inequality. Finally, incorporating government expenditure as a control variable highlights the role of public spending in mitigating inequality, further reinforcing the primary conclusions.

5. Conclusion and Policy Implications

This study examines the relationship between international trade and income inequality in the SADC region from 1990 to 2023, contributing to the ongoing discourse on trade liberalization and its distributional effects. The findings reveal that while trade openness has the potential to reduce income inequality, its impact is highly dependent on a country’s resource endowment and economic structure. Specifically, resource-rich countries in SADC tend to experience worsening inequality due to the concentration of resource rents among economic and political elites, while resource-poor nations benefit from more equitable income distribution through labor-intensive trade expansion.

To maximize the benefits of trade and mitigate inequality, resource-rich SADC countries should prioritize value addition, industrialization, and inclusive governance frameworks. The case of Norway’s sovereign wealth fund, which redistributes oil revenues to ensure long-term economic stability, serves as a successful model that could be adapted to the SADC context (Cerdeiro & Komaromi, 2021). Similarly, Botswana’s strategic diamond revenue management has contributed to better inequality outcomes compared to other resource-rich SADC nations (Acemoglu, Robinson & Johnson, 2003). Implementing transparent and accountable resource governance mechanisms can help ensure that trade-driven economic growth translates into broader societal benefits.

For lower-income SADC countries, targeted trade strategies that emphasize labor-intensive industries and manufacturing are critical in reducing inequality. The experiences of Malaysia and Vietnam provide valuable lessons. Malaysia’s export-driven industrialization policy prioritized manufacturing-led job creation, significantly reducing income disparities (Jacoby, 2020). Similarly, Vietnam’s trade policies focused on developing labor-intensive industries and investing in workforce upskilling, ensuring that trade liberalization fostered inclusive economic growth (Franco & Gerussi, 2013). Adopting similar approaches in SADC can enhance the region’s participation in global trade while promoting equitable economic opportunities.

Beyond trade policies, investments in human capital education, healthcare, and infrastructure are essential to ensuring that trade benefits are accessible to a broader population. Strengthening intra-regional trade within SADC can also help mitigate the negative effects of global trade by diversifying export markets and fostering economic resilience.

In conclusion, while international trade has the potential to reduce inequality, its benefits are not automatic. Without complementary policies, trade openness can exacerbate pre-existing disparities, particularly in resource-rich economies. To harness trade as a tool for inclusive growth, SADC countries must implement comprehensive industrial policies, equitable resource management strategies, and social investments. These measures will ensure that trade-driven growth is sustainable and inclusive, and contributes to long-term economic development in the region.

Availability of Data and Materials

Data and relevant files are available upon reasonable request.

Appendix

Appendix A. Categorization of SADC Countries

Rich Resource Endowments

Low Resource Endowments

South Africa: Coal, Diamonds, Iron ore, Chromium

Comoros

Botswana: Diamonds

Eswatini

Angola: Diamonds

Lesotho

Congo, DRC: Gold, Diamonds, Cobalt, Copper

Madagascar

Mozambique: Aluminum

Malawi

Namibia: Uranium, Diamonds, Zinc, Salt, Copper, Lead

Mauritius

Tanzania: Tanzanite, Gold, Diamond, Silver

Seychelles

Zambia: Copper, Cobalt

Zimbabwe: Platinum, Chrome, Gold, Coal, Diamonds

Appendix B. Robustness Checks-International Trade on Income Inequality, 1990-2021

OLS

2SLS

Full

Full

Full

Full

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

International Trade

0.738***

0.668**

−2.166***

−2.459***

(0.266)

(0.261)

(0.761)

(0.784)

ICT Exports

−0.0289

−0.0269

−0.0192

−0.0148

(0.0200)

(0.0196)

(0.0262)

(0.0265)

Government Final Consumption

0.0003***

0.0005***

(0.0001)

(0.0001)

Natural Resources

0.0542***

0.0580***

0.126***

0.136***

(0.0188)

(0.0185)

(0.0307)

(0.0314)

GDP Per Capita

0.0004***

0.0005***

−0.0001

−0.0001

(0.0001)

(0.0001)

(0.0002)

(0.0002)

Human Development Index

1.726***

1.497***

2.274***

1.986***

(0.425)

(0.422)

(0.549)

(0.556)

Foreign Direct Investment

−0.0102

−0.0070

0.0474***

0.0507***

(0.0123)

(0.0121)

(0.0147)

(0.0149)

Household Consumption Exp. (log)

−0.0478

−0.104

−0.214

−0.274

(0.134)

(0.133)

(0.166)

(0.167)

Population (log)

−4.205***

−3.900***

(1.000)

(0.984)

Area (log)

−6.802***

−6.825***

(1.146)

(1.122)

constant

139.4***

139.5***

(14.20)

(13.90)

Other Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Countries

15

15

15

15

No. Observations

220

220

220

220

R-Squared

0.332

0.363

−0.148

−0.166

Res

Res

Res

Res

International Trade

1.316***

1.202***

−6.924**

−6.815**

(0.387)

(0.378)

(2.948)

(2.808)

ICT Exports

−0.0356

−0.0201

0.169

0.191

(0.101)

(0.0987)

(0.242)

(0.235)

Government Final Consumption

0.0003***

0.0007**

(0.0001)

(0.0003)

Natural Resources

0.0447**

0.0505**

0.240***

0.243***

(0.0140)

(0.0164)

(0.0858)

(0.0828)

GDP Per Capita

−0.0037

0.0003

0.0052

0.0129

(0.0079)

(0.0086)

(0.0292)

(0.0285)

Human Development Index

1.174

1.054

−0.0661

−0.194

(1.013)

(0.792)

(1.708)

(1.654)

Foreign Direct Investment

−0.0076

−0.0017

0.0950***

0.0963***

(0.0164)

(0.0171)

(0.0359)

(0.0346)

Household Consumption Exp. (log)

0.372

0.223

0.877

0.594

(0.627)

(0.602)

(0.687)

(0.640)

Population (log)

−4.227***

−3.746***

(0.962)

(1.036)

Area (log)

−12.44**

−11.96**

(3.839)

(3.507)

constant

217.5***

211.5***

(25.95)

(25.31)

Other Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Countries

8

8

8

8

No. Observations

115

115

115

115

R-Squared

0.448

0.485

−2.136

−1.917

Low-Res

Low-Res

Low-Res

Low-Res

International Trade

−0.133

0.0102

−0.180

0.293

(0.327)

(0.304)

(0.548)

(0.697)

ICT Exports

−0.0272*

−0.0349**

−0.0272

−0.0313*

(0.0162)

(0.0151)

(0.0170)

(0.0170)

Government Final Consumption

−0.0027***

−0.0014*

(0.0006)

(0.0008)

Natural Resources

0.0285

−0.0469

−0.0112

−0.0688

(0.0689)

(0.0626)

(0.0472)

(0.0589)

GDP Per Capita

0.0003*

0.0003*

0.0003

0.0004*

(0.0001)

(0.0001)

(0.0001)

(0.0002)

Human Development Index

1.569

2.692**

2.252***

2.817***

(0.901)

(1.037)

(0.582)

(0.605)

Foreign Direct Investment

−0.0349

−0.0210

−0.0343

−0.0329

(0.0257)

(0.0205)

(0.0213)

(0.0210)

Household Consumption Exp. (log)

−0.128

−0.218

−0.280**

−0.356**

(0.444)

(0.315)

(0.139)

(0.144)

Population (log)

−7.439

−11.22**

(4.682)

(3.045)

Area (log)

−2.589

−1.529

(3.143)

(2.683)

constant

102.2***

105.7***

(15.55)

(14.39)

Other Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Countries

7

7

7

7

No. Observations

105

105

105

105

R-Squared

0.418

0.509

0.312

0.335

Conflicts of Interest

We declare no competing or conflict of interest.

References

[1] Acemoglu, D. (2003). Cross‐Country Inequality Trends. The Economic Journal, 113, F121-F149.
https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00100
[2] Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2003). An African Success Story: Botswana. In D. Rodrik (Ed.), Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth (pp. 80-119). Princeton University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400845897-006
[3] Anderson, E. (2005). Openness and Inequality in Developing Countries: A Review of Theory and Recent Evidence. World Development, 33, 1045-1063.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.04.003
[4] Aradhyula, S., Rahman, T., & Seenivasan, K. (2007). Impact of International Trade on Income and Income Inequality Impact of International Trade on Income and Income Inequality.
https://www.researchgate.net/publication/23507114_Impact_of_International_Trade_on_Income_and_Income_Inequality
[5] Baldwin, R. (2016). The Great Convergence. Harvard University Press.
https://doi.org/10.2307/j.ctv24w655w
[6] Basu, A. K., & Chau, N. H. (2018). Contributions to the Economics of International Labor Standards. World Scientific Studies in International Economics, 59, 444.
[7] Borrs, L., & Knauth, F. (2021). Trade, Technology, and the Channels of Wage Inequality. European Economic Review, 131, Article 103607.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2020.103607
[8] Calderón, C., Cantú, C., & Zeufack, A. G. (2020). Trade Integration, Export Patterns, and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa.
https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/entities/publication/fbaeb2d1-47f3-5711-8411-c7e00cbf6df5
[9] Cerdeiro, D. A., & Komaromi, A. (2021). Trade and Income in the Long Run: Are There Really Gains, and Are They Widely Shared? Review of International Economics, 29, 703-731.
https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12494
[10] Choi, C. (2006). Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Domestic Income Inequality? Applied Economics Letters, 13, 811-814.
https://doi.org/10.1080/13504850500400637
[11] Cobham, A., & Sumner, A. (2013). Is It All about the Tails? the Palma Measure of Income Inequality. SSRN Electronic Journal.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2366974
[12] Collier, P., & Goderis, B. (2012). Commodity Prices and Growth: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Economic Growth, 17, 35-65.
[13] de Melo, J., Gourdon, J., & Maystre, N. (2011). Openness, Inequality and Poverty: Endowments Matter. SSRN Electronic Journal.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1313756
[14] Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2004). Trade, Growth, and Poverty. The Economic Journal, 114, F22-F49.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0013-0133.2004.00186.x
[15] Dorn, F., Fuest, C., & Potrafke, N. (2021). Trade Openness and Income Inequality: New Empirical Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3892627
[16] Felbermayr, G., Gröschl, J., Egger, P., Feyrer, J., Jung, B., Kleinert, J., Larch, M., & Bernhofen, D. (2011). Natural Disasters and the Effect of Trade on Income: A New Panel IV Approach.
https://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/eecrev/v58y2013icp18-30.html
[17] Franco, C., & Gerussi, E. (2013). Trade, Foreign Direct Investments (FDI) and Income Inequality: Empirical Evidence from Transition Countries. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 22, 1131-1160.
https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2011.647048
[18] Ganaie, A. A., Bhat, S. A., & Kamaiah, B. (2018). Macro-Determinants of Income Inequality: An Empirical Analysis in Case of India. Economics Bulletin, 38, 309-325.
[19] Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2007). Distributional Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries Distributional Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w12885
[20] Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2016). The Effects of Trade Policy. In Handbook of Commercial Policy (pp. 161-206). Elsevier.
https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hescop.2016.04.002
[21] Harrison, A., McLaren, J., & McMillan, M. (2011). Recent Perspectives on Trade and Inequality. Annual Review of Economics, 3, 261-289.
https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.economics.102308.124451
[22] Herzer, D., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2013). Inward and Outward FDI and Income Inequality: Evidence from Europe. Review of World Economics, 149, 395-422.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0148-3
[23] Jacoby, S. M. (2020). Finance and Labor: Perspectives on Risk, Inequality, and Democracy. Institute for Research on Labor and Employment, 4, 248-253.
[24] Jauch, H. (2011). Time to Turn the Tide: Tackling Poverty, Inequality and Unemployment in Southern Africa.
https://library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/08221.pdf
[25] Jaumotte, F., Papageorgiou, C., & Lall, S. (2008). Rising Income Inequality: Technology, or Trade and Financial Globalization? SSRN Electronic Journal.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1175363
[26] Jonathan Gimba, O., Seraj, M., & Ozdeser, H. (2021). What Drives Income Inequality in Sub‐Saharan Africa and Its Sub‐Regions? An Examination of Long‐Run and Short-Run Effects. African Development Review, 33, 729-741.
https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8268.12603
[27] Kolawole, O. (2016). Effect of Trade on Income Inequality in Sub-Saharan Africa: Empirical Evidence from Fractional Regression Kolawole Ogundari.
https://aec.afdb.org/sites/default/files/2019/10/07/effect_of_trade_on_income_inequality_in_sub_saharan_africa.pdf
[28] Lee, J., & Wie, D. (2015). Technological Change, Skill Demand, and Wage Inequality: Evidence from Indonesia. World Development, 67, 238-250.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.10.020
[29] Lin, F., & Fu, D. (2016). Trade, Institution Quality and Income Inequality. World Development, 77, 129-142.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.08.017
[30] Mahesh, M. (2016). The Effects of Trade Openness on Income Inequality-Evidence from BRIC Countries. Economics Bulletin, 36, 1751-1761.
[31] Martin, M. (2022). The Crisis of Extreme Inequality in SADC Fighting Austerity and the COVID-19 Pandemic. Development Finance International.
[32] Mayer, J., & Wood, A. (2001). South Asia’s Export Structure in a Comparative Perspective. Oxford Development Studies, 29, 5-29.
https://doi.org/10.1080/13600810124897
[33] McMillan, M., & Rodrik, D. (2011). Globalization, Structural Change, and Productivity Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 17143.
https://www.nber.org/papers/w17143
[34] Milanovic, B. (2016). Global Inequality. Harvard University Press.
https://doi.org/10.4159/9780674969797
[35] Munir, K., & Bukhari, M. (2020). Impact of Globalization on Income Inequality in Asian Emerging Economies. International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy, 40, 44-57.
https://doi.org/10.1108/ijssp-08-2019-0167
[36] Nigai, S. (2022). Selection Effects, Inequality, and Aggregate Gains from Trade. Journal of International Economics, 142, Article 103752.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2023.103752
[37] Odusola, A. F., Cornia, G. A., Bhorat, H., Conceição, P., & Regional Bureau for Africa (2017). Income Inequality Trends in Sub-Saharan Africa: Divergence, Determinants and Consequences.
https://www.undp.org/africa/publications/income-inequality-trends-sub-saharan-africa-divergence-determinants-and-consequences
[38] Pavcnik, N. (2017). The Impact of Trade on Inequality in Developing Countries, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 12331. CEPR Press.
https://cepr.org/publications/dp12331
[39] Roser, M., & Cuaresma, J. C. (2016). Why Is Income Inequality Increasing in the Developed World? Review of Income and Wealth, 62, 1-27.
https://doi.org/10.1111/roiw.12153
[40] Ross, M. L. (2001). Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World Politics, 53, 325-361.
https://doi.org/10.1353/wp.2001.0011
[41] Silva, J. A. (2007). Trade and Income Inequality in a Less Developed Country: The Case of Mozambique. Economic Geography, 83, 111-136.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1944-8287.2007.tb00339.x
[42] Solt, F. (2020). Measuring Income Inequality across Countries and over Time: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database. Social Science Quarterly, 101, 1183-1199.
https://doi.org/10.1111/ssqu.12795
[43] Te Velde, D. W. (2017). Industrialization through Trade: Trade Policy Tools for Industrialization. ODI Research Paper.
[44] Topalova, P. (2010). Factor Immobility and Regional Impacts of Trade Liberalization: Evidence on Poverty from India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 1-41.
https://doi.org/10.1257/app.2.4.1
[45] UNCTAD (2020). World Investment Report 2020: International Production beyond the Pandemic.
https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/wir2020_en.pdf
[46] Zakaria, M., & Fida, B. A. (2016). Trade Openness and Income Inequality in China and the SAARC Region. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 30, 33-44.
https://doi.org/10.1111/apel.12152

Copyright © 2025 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.