Goal Achieving Probabilities of Mean-Variance Strategies in a Market with Regime-Switching Volatility ()
1. Introduction
In the financial world, an investor is routinely subjected to finding strategies that offer higher returns with reduced risks. In his seminal paper [1], Nobel prize laureate Markowitz introduced the myopic (single period) mean-variance portfolio management problem where one calibrates the amount of wealth invested in risky assets (stocks) and a riskless asset (bond) in such a way that it minimizes the variance of a terminal wealth while targeting an average end return. Since then, scores of innovative research problems arose related to his original static model as well as dynamic extensions in both discrete and continuous time, as seen for example in the following recent papers: [2] [3] [4].
It’s worth noting that since the unconstrained mean-variance approach is solely based on averaged return, then an investor might experience undesired marked scenarios such as returns below a safe investment in a bank account with guaranteed interest rate or even worst events such as bankruptcy. In an effort to reduce the probability of encountering these undesired scenarios while still aiming for the target wealth at the end of the investment horizon, Zhou and Li [5] devised a hybrid strategy that we will call here the switch-when-safe strategy. More precisely, in a continuous-time setting under a Black-Scholes market model with deterministic parameters, the investor follows the optimal unconstrained mean-variance strategy up to the first (random) moment, if it occurs, where he could reinvest all of his cumulative wealth in a riskless asset so that it would generate the desired wealth at the end of the investment horizon. In their paper, they discovered the following astonishing properties:
● The goal-achieving probability depends on neither the initial wealth nor the desired terminal wealth;
● The goal-achieving probability has an explicit expression in terms of market parameters and time horizon;
● The goal-achieving probability has a universal lower bound of 0.80, which depend on neither the market parameters nor the time horizon.
Still, in the context of deterministic market parameters in a Black Scholes model with stock prices driven by Brownian motions, these same properties were also uncovered when one considers cone-constrained mean-variance strategies such as no short-selling strategies [6] [7]. In this paper, we wish to explore if these properties carry on to more general market models for example by considering a Black-Scholes model with added randomness, more precisely, while maintaining deterministic interest for the riskless asset and deterministic drift parameters for the risky asset, we will allow the volatility parameter of the risky asset to change, depending on the state of a continuous-time Markov chain, independent of the stock prices driven by Brownian motions.
2. Market Model and Regime-Switching Mean-Variance Strategy
The market model is composed of a riskless asset and m risky assets with a volatility matrix
depending of an independent Markov chain
. The price
of the riskless asset a timet follow the dynamics given by the ODE:
while the price of the risky assets follow the dynamics given by the SDEs:
where
are independent standard Brownian motions and
is a continuous-time Markov chain with a finite set of states
.
Let
,
,
and
be the investor portfolio:
is the amount invested in the ith stock at time t. Then the self-financing wealth process X of the investor is driven by the SDE
A mean-variance strategy
is one that minimizes the variance of the terminal wealth
under the constraint that the expected terminal wealth satisfies
where
.
Zhou and Yin [8] showed that, for a regime-switching volatility model, this optimal strategy is given by
where the Lagrange multiplier
is given by
and
is the solution to the following ODE system
where
and
is the infinitesimal generator of Markov chain
.
Consequently, following Itô’s formula, the wealth process
of the mean-variance startegy can be expressed as
where
This form is well-suited to the computations in the next section.
3. Switch-When-Safe Mean-Variance Strategy and Goal Achieving Probabilities
Consider the following stopping time:
This time, if it exists, is the first moment at which the wealth is such that, invested in the riskless asset, it would have a final value equal to the targeted expected terminal wealth of the mean-variance strategy.
The switch-when-safe mean-variance strategy of [5] is defined as
Now observe that
Since
, it follows that the equality
is verified if and only if
From this condition, we see that, as it is the case in [5], the goal-achieving probability of the switch-when-safe mean-variance strategy for a regime-switching volatility model does not depend on either the initial wealth or the desired terminal wealth.
Now let us find an expression for the goal-achieving probabilities in the case of a model with one risky asset that is W is reduced to a one-dimensional brownian motion, let
First, according to Buffington and Elliottt [9], the characteristic function of the diffusion process Y is given by
where
is a S-dimensional vector of ones.
Let
represent the barrier, if
is the stopping time defined by
then
By introducing the Wiener-Hopf factorization of the process
that is to say, the couple
which solves for every
where
with
,
, Q the infinitesimal generator and
the
identity matrix, then, following Jiang and Pistorius [10], the associated Laplace transform
of the random variable
is given by
therefore, through Laplace transform inversion, we deduce
Moreover, since the ratio
is constant for
then according to Hieber [11] the last expression is reduced to
Both expressions can easily be evaluated numerically. However, it is worth mentioning that, even if one could find explicit forms for the exponential matrices (which is the case for
for example) appearing in these expressions, searching for possible closed-formed formulas for the integrals involved could prove to be quite challenging.
One notable exception is the trivial case where all possible values of the volatility matrix are reduced to a single constant matrix. Then we have
that is
revert to a standard Brownian motion with drift and according to [5]:
Figure 1 shows the probabilities in this case as a function of
.
![]()
Figure 1. Goal-achieving probabilities as a function of
.
For the numerical study of lower bound probabilities, we will suppose hereon that we have one risky asset, the parameters r and
are constant, and the volatility parameter
follows a 2-state continuous-time Markov chain with an infinitesimal generator Q taking the form
where
. In this case, the constant interest r allows us to have the explicit solution to the ODE system
with
Furthermore, since
is 2-state Markov chain, the matrix
can be written explicitly [11] as
where
are the real positive roots of the quartic equation
Following the Cayley-Hamilton theorem we then have
which leads us to an explicit expression for the Laplace transform
. We will use it in our numerical computation of the goal-achieving probabilities
.
As an example, consider a market model with a single asset and a two-state volatility:
We can compute the goal-achieving probabilities
like in Figure 1 and find a lower bound for them as a function of the different values of the stock’s regime-switching volatility. Table 1 gives the lower bound probabilities, assuming the initial regime-switching state is
.
Clearly one observes that, in presence of a true regime-switching volatility model (
), the lower bound probabilities cross the threshold of its deterministic model counterpart. Moreover, as
takes on larger values while
takes on lower values the lower bound probabilites gets fairly small, for example
![]()
Table 1. Lower bounds of goal-achieving probabilities.
if we take
and
the lower bound probability decreases to a mere 0.166.
4. Limit Cases of Goal Achieving Probabilities
Assume now that Q depends on a parameter k:
with
. We will study the first passage time probabilities when either
or
, which corresponds respectively to the case where the regime-switching jumps appear with high frequency or are scarce.
●
(average time to next jump tends to zero)
and therefore
The barrier
where
.
We can also show after tedious calculations that
where
and
.
This expression corresponds to the Laplace transform of the inverse Gaussian (or Wald) density with mean
and shape parameter
, therefore
For the single asset model of the previous section, with regime-switching volatilities
and
, Figure 2 below shows the goal-achieving probabilites for increasing values of k.
●
(average time to next jump tends to infinity)
and therefore
The barrier
.
In this case, we can obtain the limit of the passage-time probability in a straightforward manner. Since the average time to the next jumps tends towards infinity, the Markov chain
will have a tendency to stay at its intital state
, thus
and therefore
For the same example as above, Figure 3 illustrates this result for decreasing values of k.
![]()
Figure 2. Goal-achieving probabilities for increasing k.
![]()
Figure 3. Goal-achieving probabilities for decreasing k.
5. Conclusion
In the context of a Black-Scholes market model with stochastic volatility processes driven by a continuous-time Markov chain with finite states, we obtained tractable expressions for the goal-achieving probabilities of switch-when-safe strategies as first introduced by Zhou and Li [5]. We observed that the goal-achieving probabilities are independent of the value of the initial wealth and targeted terminal mean wealth, a property shared with the standard Black-Scholes market counterpart. Unfortunately, it appears that a universal lower bound for these probabilities does not exist for the set of all possible market parameters and infinitesimal generators of the Markovian process as illustrated by our numerical studies. Finally, when the Markovian regime is allowed to either attain higher or lower frequencies than the first-passage time probabilities expressions converge to closed-form formulas.
Acknowledgements
The second author sincerely thanks the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada (NSERC) for its support.