Stop-Loss Reinsurance Threshold for Dependent Risks

Abstract

This paper examines stop-loss reinsurance threshold for a pool of dependent risk, which is motivated by the fact that insurance penetration in Africa is far below the world’s average rate. The study applies convex combination of quantile measures to produce a linear function with both insurer and reinsurer cost functions which are then minimized to arrive at an optimal retention threshold. Results indicate that threshold is determined by the proportion of risk-sharing, and that the model performs better even with small sample sizes based on Monte Carlo simulation. Finally, it is noted that sustainability of decentralized insurance requires modelling of dependence structure for realistic pricing and reserving methods.

Share and Cite:

Mandia, A. , Weke, P. and Mung’atu, J. (2023) Stop-Loss Reinsurance Threshold for Dependent Risks. Journal of Mathematical Finance, 13, 304-320. doi: 10.4236/jmf.2023.133019.

1. Introduction

Recent decades have seen rapid growth of decentralized schemes in insurance which are supported by internet technology, with practices like online peer-to-peer insurance, mutual aid and micro-insurance. Decentralizes schemes arose as a solution to low insurance penetration rate in Africa at an average of 2% way below a world-average of 7%, which [1] stated was caused by low financial literacy, unaffordable premiums and infancy of the insurance industry in Africa. Decentralization disrupted traditional business with a goal to broaden penetration by complementing insurance operations, through revival of centuries-old community loss sharing traditions that can be traced back to the Roman Empire, as per [2] . However, decentralized insurance schemes have been plagued by high failure rate in short period of time. [3] provided an example of a giant Chinese online mutual aid platform Xianghubao which collapsed in three years of operations after amassing more than 100 million policyholders within a year of operations, and other defunct peer-to-peer schemes.

One theory put forward to explain high failure rate is nature of policyholders: while traditionally insurance collects large numbers of homogeneous people such that Central Limiting Theorem applies, [4] discerned that decentralized schemes have close relations such as co-workers and neighbours. This presents two problems: individual risks are not approximately independent and schemes have relatively smaller number of members. Reinsurance was introduced to the schemes as a control strategy which has shown success in stabilizing decentralized finance, discussed in [5] and [6] . The superiority stop-loss reinsurance in minimizing the variance of insurer loss is well documented in actuarial literature such as [7] . Reinsurance threshold, known as retention limit, is a cut-off point between the two parties and a point of particular interest, because it determines how much a scheme has to pay as reinsurance premium. The threshold can be derived from a viewpoint of insurer, reinsurer or both (combined approach) acceptable by both sides.

This paper proposes to apply a combined approach in constructing stop-loss retention threshold for a pool of dependent risks. The methodology is divided into two main stages: the first step is to leverage definition of reinsurance to build separate functions representing costs of insurer and reinsurer. This is achieved by using stop-loss reinsurance to reconstruct two aggregate random variables for insurer and reinsurer, which when added by premium form cost functions. The second step involves minimizing aggregate cost of the whole scheme. This is accomplished using convex combination of cost functions measured at quantile measures to produce a linear function, which is minimized to arrive at an optimal retention threshold. Gamma-distributed losses were used to demonstrate viability of the solution. Results are tested through Monte Carlo simulation by ensuring that optimized values loss tend to zero with each iteration and comparison is performed with a variance-covariance method. The approach was selected, because convex combination optimization increases the speed at which algorithm converges to the solution, and results can be extended to a system of linear equations.

The suggested approach found that optimal threshold is defined within the survival function of the aggregate loss, which is consistent with the definition of quantile measure for non-negative random variables. Survival function is monotone decreasing, thus providing natural upper and lower boundaries to the optimized loss function, and results to consistent threshold estimates for both small and large pools. An assumption of comonotonicity was applied to construct the aggregate loss function, and since comonotonic vector provides the highest risk for any combination of individual risks, resulting threshold would exaggerate actual risk providing a safety loading for adverse experience.

Results showed that reinsurer has to bear larger portion of aggregate risk than insurer for a portfolio with high dependence, for stop-loss reinsurance to be effective. By extension, dependence structure influences optimal share of aggregate loss between an insurer and reinsurer. As reinsurance incurs a cost in form of the premium to an insurer, there is an incentive for higher threshold in order to attract low reinsurance premium. With comonotonic risks findings showed that optimal threshold was obtained when more weight was on the reinsurer than insurer, with little variation in relation to parameter controlling cost functions. This means that effective risk management of dependent risks calls for a lower reinsurance threshold than independent risks.

The implication of this work is to challenge assumption of independence in decentralized schemes, despite being acceptable on conventional insurance which has a larger group size with either homogeneous (independent and identically distributed) or heterogeneous risks (independent but not identically distributed). For industry regulators, reinsurance with decentralized insurance has to involve different set of margins owing to the nature of risks it undertakes. Such outcome is consistent with the hypothesis that traditional reinsurance may fail to stabilize decentralized insurance schemes because of use of traditional margins and not considering dependency structure. This regulation approach has shown success with decentralized finance in developing countries as investigated by [8] using vehicles such as Savings and Credit Cooperative Societies (SaCCoS) and mobile money. [9] discusses similarities and differences between decentralization in finance versus insurance, and concludes that both are good candidates for inclusive financial practices.

This paper relates to optimal reinsurance problems, which involve a class of infinite dimensional (constrained) optimization problems whose solution search for an optimal function in lieu of a parameter value. The solution is guided by Pareto Optimality pioneered by [10] [11] [12] [13] . Determination of retention threshold by minimization of cost is centred on measures of risk beyond classical variance/standard deviation methods with a goal of complementing risk measurement applied in other financial institutions such as the banking sector’s Basel Accords. The method has been applied by several authors for single ( [14] [15] [16] ) and multiple risks ( [17] [18] [19] ). In addition, there are a number of contributions to the literature. First this work adds to dependency analysis for multiple risks by establishing a connect between risk measures in [17] and cost analysis for non independent risks in [20] . The paper contributes to quantitative analysis of decentralized insurance in [21] by relaxing assumption of independence which understates claims leading to liquidity problems. Finally this paper derives a simple threshold easily understood by practitioners, which is an important area of inclusive finance that encourage hybrid products between banking and insurance services; a merger which was suggested in [22] .

The rest of paper is organized as follows: Section 2 is a background on sums of random variables, and Section 3 discusses definition of stop-loss reinsurance. Quantile risk measure is revisited in Section 4, before the optimal retention threshold derived in Section 5. Section 6 presents numerical applications and a conclusion is done in Section 7.

2. Sum of Random Variables

Aggregate risk is made up of several individual risks, as such the sum of random variables is of special interest in risk aggregation. By extension, characteristics of S in (1) are determined by relationship between individual random variables, and a joint cumulative density function has all information on characteristics of a random variable.

Definition 1 (Aggregate loss) Consider n individuals, n i = 1 , 2 , , n each facing risk X i represented by distribution function F X ( x ) = P r ( X i x ) and a survival function S X ( x ) = P ( X i > x ) ; the aggregate loss of the pool is a random variable S defined as:

S = X 1 + X 2 + + X n = i = 1 n X i (1)

Assuming that risks X i are independent, distribution of S is determined by well-known convolution methods with an aid of algebraic manipulation, where S is a product of marginal distributions shown in (2), with statistical properties similar to individual risks. The assumption is undertaken to simplify calculations for reasonable large pool which tends to normalization, since in real world risks cannot be completely independent. Note that, in cases where risks are significantly dependent, independence assumption may understate or overstate aggregate risk.

F S ( s ) = F ( x 1 , x 2 , x n ) = i = 1 n F ( x i ) (2)

Positive dependence means that individual X i ’s move in the same direction, such that when there is perfect positive dependence then distribution of S is said to be comonotonic with cumulative distribution is defined in (3). Comonotonic sum results into the riskiest portfolio in any combination of risks X i ’s, and has been studied by many such as [23] [24] [25] and [26] ,

F S ( s ) = min { F X 1 ( x 1 ) , F X 2 ( x 2 ) , , F X n ( x n ) } (3)

Negative dependence results when random variables X i ’s move in opposite direction, effectively compensating each others’ risks therefore decreasing aggregate loss S. When individual risks have perfectly negative dependency, distribution of S is said to be countermonotonic defined in (4). Counter-monotonic sum forms the lowest-risk portfolio and by extension, internal hedging mechanism, which is an interesting problem in risk management.

F S ( s ) = max { F X 1 ( x 1 ) , F X 2 ( x 2 ) , , F X n ( x n ) } (4)

However, research in counter monotonicity beyond two dimensions ( n 3 ) is limited by absence of universal mathematical definition; including pairwise counter monotonicity, d-countermonotonicity, joint mixability, complete mixability and c x -countermonotonicity as investigated by [27] [28] [29] [30] and [31] .

3. Stop-Loss Reinsurance

Reinsurance divides an individual risk X i between insurer and reinsurer, either proportionally or non-proportionally, which are further discussed as reinsurance types in [32] . The Broker Model illustrated in Figure 1 was coined by [33] for a decentralized insurance setting, and has similar structure to reinsurance in traditional insurance.

Under Broker Model, aggregate loss S is divided amongst individuals using a Pareto-efficient and financially fair rule called the Conditional Mean Risk Sharing by [26] . Using this method, a participant i must contribute expected value of loss X i brought into the pool conditional to total loss S experienced by all members, i.e. the contribution of each participant is the average part of total loss attributed to the risk added to the pool.

Definition 2 (Conditional Mean Risk Sharing) Let x i be realizations of loss X i and s = i = 1 n x i be the realization of S. There exists measurable functions h 1, n , h 2, n , , h n , n such that:

h i , n ( S ) = E [ X i | S ] , i = 1,2, , n . (5)

Conditional Mean Risk Sharing is Pareto efficient because the whole loss is allocated as shown in (6), and financially fair because mean of individual contribution is the expected value of the whole pool as in (7).

i = 1 n h i , n ( S ) = i = 1 n E [ X i | S = s ] = s . (6)

E [ h i , n ( S ) ] = E [ E [ X i | S ] ] = E [ X i ] = μ i for i = 1,2, , n (7)

Now to define stop-loss random variables, let the proportion of insurer be X I and that of reinsurer be X R , then each individual loss is a combination of component random variables detailed in (8).

X i = X I + X R (8)

Definition 3 (Stop-loss random variables) Let an individual risk threshold be w i , such that insurer covers ( 0, w i ) of the loss and retain min ( X i , w i ) while the reinsurer cover ( w i , ) , the stop-loss random variables are defined in (9):

X I = { X i , X i w i w i , X i > w i = min ( X i , w i ) = X i w i and X R = { 0 , X i w i X i w i , X i > w i = max { ( X i w i ) , 0 } = ( X i w i ) + (9)

Assumptions

1) Losses resulting from X 1 , X 2 , , X n obey zero-augmented probability distributions i.e. P r [ X i = 0 ] > 0 for each i.

(a) Model visualization (b) Model working

Figure 1. Illustration of broker model.

2) The mean and variance of individual losses X i are finite and non-negative, that is, μ i = E [ X i ] > 0 and σ i 2 = Var [ X i ] > 0 respectively.

3) For the pool S, retention threshold w n is the sum of individual retentions, that is, there exists w 1, n , w 2, n , , w n , n such that w n = i = 1 n w i , n

From definition of X R the distribution function can be derived as F X R ( x ) = F X ( x + w ) . For the insurer, distribution function of X I is derived in (10).

F X I ( x ) = { F X i ( x ) , x w i 1 , x > w i (10)

When a reinsurer has no knowledge of underlying claim distribution, retention threshold is derived from a conditional random variable X R = X i w i | X i > w i . By setting Z i = X i w i simplifies to X R = Z i | Z i > 0 . The distribution of threshold is given by:

F X R ( x ) = P r ( X R x ) = P r ( X i x + w | X i > w i ) = F ( x + w i ) F ( w i ) 1 F ( w i ) = F ( x + w i ) F ( w i ) P r ( X i > w i ) (11)

Estimation of threshold from reinsurer point of view applies Extreme Value Theorem (EVT) for right-tailed distributions, since EVT models extreme events using statistical tools. For instance, eyeball inspection approach (EIA) uses mean excess plot to determine appropriate threshold, which has a disadvantage of testing individual risk thresholds in isolation, therefore neglecting diversification effect in the pool. Other methods incorporate aggregate loss function for better approximations.

4. Quantile Risk Measure

α-quantile risk measure is also known as value-at-risk (VaR) in financial models, and mathematically defined as (12).

Definition 4 (Value-at-Risk) The α-quantile measure for a random variable X where F X ( x ) = P r [ X x ] is defined as:

VaR α ( X ) = inf { x | F X ( x ) α } , α ( 0,1 ) VaR α ( X ) = sup { x | F X ( x ) α } , α ( 0,1 ) (12)

A solution to the equation

P r { X > VaR α ( X ) } = α P r { X VaR α ( X ) } = 1 α (13)

4.1. Properties

Value-at-risk satisfies the following properties for a risk measure ρ ( ) :

Normalization: The risk of nothing is zero, hence ρ [ 0 ] = 0 .

Positive homogeinity: Risk of a portfolio is proportional to the size, such that for any positive constant β the equation ρ [ β X ] = β ρ [ X ] applies. By extension, let X and g ( X ) be real-valued random variables, if g is continuous and non-decreasing then VaR α ( g ( X ) ) = g ( VaR α ( X ) ) .

Monotonicity: A random variable preceding another in the convex order has a higher risk between the two, i.e. for two risks X and Y if X < Y then ρ [ X ] > ρ [ Y ] .

Translation Invariance: Addition of a constant (or risk-free asset) to a portfolio changes total risk by similar proportion, that is, for any positive constant γ , ρ [ X + γ ] = ρ [ X ] γ .

VaR is a not a coherent risk measure because of not satisfying additivity property. Under some special cases such as elliptic distributions VaR satisfies the property:

Subadditivity: Additivity is the risk reducing property, also known as diversification property where for two risks X and Y, ρ ( X + Y ) ρ ( X ) + ρ ( Y ) .

4.2. VaR for Comonotonic Risks

In place of independence assumption, when the sum (1) has a complicated dependency structure that may be too tedious to calculate, there is an acceptable practice to replace it with a less desirable sum using prudential assumption. Comonotonic sum of S denoted as S c belongs to the same Fréchet class and has similar properties ( [26] ), but S c has heavier tails which means larger variance, resulting into higher aggregate risk.

Theorem 1 (for comonotonic risks). Assume the risks X i ’s are comonotonic and form a random vector ( X 1 c , X 2 c , , X n c ) whose sum S c = X 1 c + X 2 c + + X n c is also comonotonic, then:

VaR α ( S c ) = VaR α ( X 1 c + X 2 c + + X n c ) = i = 1 n VaR α [ X i ] , α ( 0,1 ) (14)

Proof. Sum is the addition of individual comonotonic variables; let U be a uniform random variable in the interval [ 0,1 ] such that:

S c = d F X 1 1 ( U ) + F X 2 1 ( U ) + + F X n 1 ( U ) = g ( U )

Now let g be a non-decreasing, left continuous function and α ( 0,1 ) , then

F g ( X ) 1 ( α ) = g ( F X 1 ( α ) )

F g ( X ) 1 + ( α ) = g ( F X 1 ( 1 α ) )

It follows, from the definitions, that:

VaR α ( S c ) = i = 1 n VaR α [ X i ] , α ( 0 , 1 )

5. Retention Threshold Using Quantile Measure

For a comonotonic portfolio of risks S c which follows assumption 3, the stop-loss aggregate random variables S I and S R for an insurer and reinsurer respectively are defined as sum of individual random variables in (9) such that:

S c = S I + S R (15)

Reinsurance requires a fee, which in this paper will be defined as pure premium P without a loading as shown in (16):

P = E ( S R ) = E [ ( S w n ) + ] = w n S ( s ) d s (16)

Note that P is a decreasing function of w n : a higher threshold attracts low premium and a lower threshold has a higher premium margin.

5.1. Cost Functions

Decentralized insurance has no capital requirements therefore total cost is the aggregate loss random variable, and any division into component variables should equal the aggregate loss in order to satisfy Pareto Optimality. Let the total cost of insurance be a random variable T: define the component costs of insurer and reinsurer as random variables T I and T R respectively as in (17).

T I = S I + P T R = S R P (17)

Next is to construct a cost model as convex combination of cost functions in (17) measured at their respective values-at-risk:

Theorem 2 (loss function). Let VaR p and VaR q be portfolio VaR for insurer and reinsurer respectively with random variables denoting costs of a insurer and reinsurer defined in (17); then aggregate loss function is a convex combination of the random variables defined in (18):

L = η VaR p ( T I ) + ( 1 η ) VaR q ( T R ) ; η [ 0 , 1 ] (18)

Parameter η determines the division of total loss between the insurer and reinsurer: if η = 0 then reinsurance company carries all costs while if η = 1 then there are no reinsurance arrangements applied; hence it sets optimal aggregate cost of the pool subject to the set value-at-risk levels for players.

5.2. Optimal Threshold

The objective of cost approach is minimization of the total cost subject to quantile risk measure in order to obtain an optimal retention level, w * . Breaking down (18) to components:

L = η VaR p ( T I ) + ( 1 η ) VaR q ( T R ) = η [ VaR p ( S w n ) + P ] + ( 1 η ) [ VaR q ( S w n ) + P ] (19)

where the premium P is defined in (16). Define a p = VaR p ( S ) and a q = VaR q ( S ) and rewrite objective function (19) such that;

L = η [ a p w n ] + ( 1 η ) ( a q w n ) + + ( 2 η 1 ) P (20)

Optimization problem becomes:

min ( L ) s .t . w n , η [ 0,1 ] a p a q (21)

Naturally, since the problem aims to align the interests of both reinsurer and insurer, four cases arise: w n < a q , w n > a q , w < a p and w n > a p . If optimal w n < a q then the pool loss is within insurer’s safety margin while w n > a q indicate that the optimal level might be unacceptable to the insurer, and w n > a p shows that the reinsurer requires (re-)insurance to manage costs. The cases are combined into three distinct ones: w n < a q , w n > a p and a q < w n a p .

Theorem 3 (loss Retention Threshold). The optimal retention level w n * is a piecewise-function (22):

w n * = ( S 1 ( s ) , w n < a q S 1 ( η β ) , a q < w n a p S 1 ( β ( η 1 ) ) , w n > a p (22)

where the parameter β is defined as:

β = 1 2 η 1 (23)

Proof. The derivative of function (20), with premium P in (16) is given as:

L = ( ( 2 η 1 ) ( 2 η 1 ) S ( w n ) , w n < a q η ( 2 η 1 ) S ( w n ) , a q < w n a p ( η 1 ) ( 2 η 1 ) S ( w n ) , w n > a p (24)

Set L = 0 to arrive at equations:

S ( w n ) = 1 S ( w n ) = η 2 η 1 S ( w n ) = η 1 2 η 1 (25)

For the sufficient condition for minimization L > 0 , recall that the derivative of a survival function S ( x ) is a hazard function characterized by non-decreasing nature; which confirms that the threshold is a minimum threshold.

A special case of η = 0.5 for model in (22) where β = .

L = η [ a p w n ] + ( 1 η ) ( a q w n ) + + ( 2 η 1 ) P = 1 2 [ ( a p w n ) + ( a q w n ) + ] (26)

Here, two cases arise which are described below:

when a q < a p

L = ( 1 2 a q , w n < a q 1 2 w n , a q < w n a p 1 2 a p , w n > a p (27)

which means that

min w n [ 0 , ) L = 1 2 a q (28)

and

w n * [ 0, a q ] (29)

when a q > a p

L = ( 1 2 a q , w n < a p 1 2 ( a p + a q w n ) , a p < w n a q 1 2 a p , w n > a q (30)

which means that

min w n [ 0 , ) L = 1 2 a p (31)

and

w n * [ 0, a p ] (32)

Therefore, aggregate function is reduced to depend on values-of-risk only as shown in (26), and threshold depends solely on the values of risk. In this case, retention has indirect relationship with the VaR of insurer a p but direct relationship with that of reinsurer a q .

6. Numerical Example

Gamma distribution was used to demonstrate application because of possession of many useful and tractable mathematical properties, such that a sum of gamma random variables is also a Gamma distribution. This means that comonotonic random variables in (8) shall be gamma as well with density function in (33).

f ( x ; α , β ) = x α 1 e β x β α Γ ( α ) for x > 0 α , β > 0 (33)

6.1. Comparison

The model was a quantile-measure extension of [21] which applied variance measures for threshold determination by using two approaches: a minimum variance derived by maximizing the covariance between insurer and reinsurer in Proposition 3.1. such that:

max w π ( w ) [ w E ( S ) + π ( w ) ] s .t w > 0 (34)

where π ( w ) = P defined in (16); which was compared to results obtained by similar approach of correlation coefficient defined as ρ , a standardized measure in Proposition 3.3 such that:

max w ρ ( S I , S R ) = Cov [ S I , S R ] Var [ S R ] Var [ S I ] s .t w > 0 (35)

where

E ( S I ) = E [ min ( S , w ) ] = E [ S ] E [ S R ]

Var [ S I ] = Var [ S ] Var [ S R ] 2 Cov [ S I , S R ]

Var [ S R ] = E [ S R ] ( 2 w E [ S R ] ) + 2 w s ( 1 F S ( s ) ) d s

Cov [ S I , S R ] = E ( S R ) [ w E ( S ) + E ( S R ) ]

The comparison applied a Gamma distribution with a mean 1, variance 2 and skewness of 3 2 where a set of values-at-risk were chosen for insurer and

reinsurer with pool sizes as little as 30 individuals up to 100,000 members, and using Monte Carlo simulation was applied to model retention thresholds. Parameter values of risk simulated were upper-quartile, p 0.75 with .05 step. [21] obtained w = 2.19654 using covariance measure and w = 1.3598 for correlation coefficient, when c o v = 0.326122 and ρ = 0.499926 respectively using analytical methods.

Results were compared with this paper’s model using numerical approximation, and noted [21] fails to perform for small samples (less than 500), but our model provides several optimal thresholds for smaller groups, as shown in Table 1. When η = 0.5 retention threshold does not depend on the survival function (constant for combinations of parameters) as summarized in Table 2.

6.2. Discussion

It is noted that optimal retention took values of η < 0.5 which suggest that optimality is achieved by ceding more risk to reinsurer. This result confirms findings of [34] and [9] that decentralised insurance benefits from stop-loss reinsurance of any form, be it losses below insurer’s deductible or selective risks in the portfolio, both of which result into relatively smaller losses.

Loss function reduces with subsequent iterations (Figure 2) which suggests convergence into a true minimum, which also happens relatively fast within a few iterations as the number of risks grows, a fact that is consistent with the

Table 1. Threshold determined by the two models.

Table 2. Optimal retention parameters when η = 0.5 .

(a) n = 30 (b) n = 50 (c) n = 100 (d) n = 500 (e) n = 1000 (f) n = 5000 (g) n = 10,000 (h) n = 50,000 (i) n = 100,000

Figure 2. Loss functions.

Central Limit Theorem. [21] variance-covariance approximation fails to perform with small samples (less than 500), but the model provides several optimal thresholds for smaller groups.

Results of the model show that threshold closely relate to reinsurer’s value at risk. Combined with the behaviour of larger samples discussed above, it suggests that decentralised insurance depends on efficient modelling of reinsurer’s value-at-risk. The stability offered by the risk sharing between the two parties is only as beneficial if insurer quotes the correct risk profile for the model, including dependency structure of its composition.

7. Conclusions

This paper presents a model for selecting retention threshold for dependent risks using value-at-risk, which was demonstrated using a numerical example. In comparison to variance measures, value-at-risk presented a better threshold for pools of all sizes and in particular it provides reliable estimation of retention threshold for small groups. This is an important result for decentralized insurance characterized by small groups which are closely-related. The fact that it is based on an arbitrary selected parameter rather than distribution function simplifies calculations and provides flexibility on application of the model.

Possible future research may consider information asymmetry between reinsurer and insurer where the two parties have different beliefs on the type and/or behaviour of aggregate loss, using either a parametric, semi-parametric or non-parametric approach. That is, the distribution of loss may present different characteristics for a reinsurer such that optimization criteria combining Extreme Value Theorem approach provides improved approximation for dependent risks.

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for the comments of two reviewers who would prefer to remain anonymous, whose valuable comments provided different angle to the work. We offer gratitude to an anonymous reviewer from University of Illinois, Urbana Campaign helped to restructure paper for the better. This research work is supported by the Pan African University through its scholarship program.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] Statica (2017) Rate of Insurance Penetration in Sub-Saharan Africa in 2017, by Country.
https://www.statista.com/statistics/727403/insurance-penetration-in-sub-saharan-africa-by-country
[2] Perry, J.S. (2006) The Roman Collegia: The Modern Evolution of an Ancient Concept. Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden.
[3] Abdikerimova, S. and Feng, R.H. (2022) Peer-to-Peer Multi-Risk Insurance and Mutual Aid. European Journal of Operational Research, 299, 735-749.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2021.09.017
[4] Feng, R.H., Liu, M. and Zhang, N. (2022) A Unified Theory of Decentralized Insurance. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4231188
[5] Banerjee, A., Duflo, E. and Hornbeck, R. (2014) Bundling Health Insurance and Microfinance in India: There Cannot Be Adverse Selection If There Is No Demand. American Economic Review, 104, 291-297. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.5.291
[6] Mandia, A.N. (2017) Isolation of Microinsurance from Commercial Insurance: A Solution to Challenges Facing Microinsurance in India? Master’s Thesis, B.S.A Crescent University, Chennai.
[7] Bowers, N.L., Gerber, H.U., Hickman, J.C., Jones, D.A. and Nesbit, C. (1997) Actuarial Mathematics. Society of Actuaries, Schaumburg.
[8] Nakato, L. (2021) Essays on the Performance of Savings Groups. PhD Thesis, University of Agder, Kristiansand.
[9] Charpentier, A., Kouakou, L., Lowe, M., Ratz, P. and Vermet, F. (2021) Collaborative Insurance Sustainability and Network Structure.
[10] Borch, K. (1960) An Attempt to Determine the Optimum Amount of Stop Loss Reinsurance. Transactions of the 16th International Congress of Actuaries, Vol. 1, 597-610.
[11] Borch, K. (1962) Equilibrium in a Reinsurance Market. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 30, 424-444. https://doi.org/10.2307/1909887
[12] Du Mouchel, W.H. (1968) The Pareto Optimality of an n-Company Reinsurance Treaty. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 1968, 165-170.
https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.1968.10413277
[13] Bühlmann, H. and Jewell, W.S. (1979) Optimal Risk Exchanges. ASTIN Bulletin: The Journal of the IAA, 10, 243-262. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0515036100005882
[14] Cai, J. and Tan, K.S. (2007) Optimal Retention for a Stop-Loss Reinsurance under the VaR and CTE Risk Measures. ASTIN Bulletin: The Journal of the IAA, 37, 93-112. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0515036100014756
[15] Tan, K.S., Weng, C.G. and Zhang, Y. (2011) Optimality of General Reinsurance Contracts under CTE Risk Measure. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 49, 175-187. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2011.03.002
[16] Cui, W., Yang, J.P. and Wu, L. (2013) Optimal Reinsurance Minimizing the Distortion Risk Measure under General Reinsurance Premium Principles. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 53, 74-85.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.03.007
[17] Cai, J. and Wei, W. (2012) Optimal Reinsurance with Positively Dependent Risks. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 50, 57-63.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2011.10.006
[18] Hu, X., Yang, H.L. and Zhang, L.Z. (2015) Optimal Retention for a Stop-Loss Reinsurance with Incomplete Information. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 65, 15-21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2015.08.005
[19] Jiang, W.J., Ren, J.D. and Zitikis, R. (2017) Optimal Reinsurance Policies under the VaR Risk Measure When the Interests of both the Cedent and the Reinsurer Are Taken into Account. Risks, 5, Article No. 11. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks5010011
[20] Cheung, K.C. and Lo, A. (2017) Characterizations of Optimal Reinsurance Treaties: A Cost-Benefit Approach. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 2017, 1-28.
https://doi.org/10.1080/03461238.2015.1054303
[21] Castaner, A. and Claramunt, M.M. (2016) Optimal Stop-Loss Reinsurance: A Dependence Analysis. Hacettepe Journal of Mathematics and Statistics, 45, 497-519.
[22] Ruchismita, R. and Churchill, C. (2012) State and Market Synergies: Insights from India’s Microinsurance Success. In: Churchill, C. and Matul, M., Eds., Protecting the Poor: A Microinsurance Compendium, Vol. 2, International Labour Organization, Geneva, 424-463.
[23] Dhaene, J., Denuit, M., Goovaerts, M.J., Kaas, R. and Vyncke, D. (2002) The Concept of Comonotonicity in Actuarial Science and Finance: Theory. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 31, 3-33. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6687(02)00134-8
[24] Vanduffel, S., et al. (2005) Comonotonicity: From Risk Measurement to Risk Management. PhD Thesis, Universiteit van Amsterdam [Host], Amsterdam.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1359809
[25] Dhaene, J., Vanduffel, S. and Goovaerts, M.J. (2008) Comonotonicity. Encyclopedia of Quantitative Risk Analysis and Assessment. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., Hoboken.
https://doi.org/10.1002/9780470061596.risk0341
[26] Denuit, M. and Dhaene, J. (2012) Convex Order and Comonotonic Conditional Mean Risk Sharing. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 51, 265-270.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2012.04.005
[27] Lee, W. and Ahn, J.Y. (2014) On the Multidimensional Extension of Countermonotonicity and Its Applications. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 56, 68-79.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2014.03.002
[28] Puccetti, G. and Wang, R.D. (2015) Extremal Dependence Concepts. Statistical Science, 30, 485-517. https://doi.org/10.1214/15-STS525
[29] Ko, B. and Ahn, J.Y. (2016) On Multivariate Countermonotonic Copulas and Their Actuarial Application. Lobachevskii Journal of Mathematics, 37, 387-396.
https://doi.org/10.1134/S199508021604003X
[30] Lee, W., Cheung, K.C. and Ahn, J.Y. (2017) Multivariate Countermonotonicity and the Minimal Copulas. Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics, 317, 589-602. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2016.12.032
[31] Ahn, J.Y. and Fuchs, S. (2020) On Minimal Copulas under the Concordance Order. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 184, 762-780.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-019-01618-4
[32] Kaas, R., Goovaerts, M., Dhaene, J. and Denuit, M. (2008) Modern Actuarial Risk Theory: Using R. Volume 128, Springer Science & Business Media, Berlin.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-70998-5
[33] Rego, M.L. and Carvalho, J.C. (2020) Insurance in Today’s Sharing Economy: New Challenges Ahead or a Return to the Origins of Insurance? In: Marano, P. and Noussia, K., Eds., InsurTech: A Legal and Regulatory View, Springer, Berlin, 27-47.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-27386-6_2
[34] Denuit, M. and Robert, C.Y. (2021) Stop-Loss Protection for a Large p2p Insurance Pool. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 100, 210-233.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2021.05.007

Copyright © 2023 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.