Share This Article:

On the Internal Consistency of the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model

Abstract Full-Text HTML XML Download Download as PDF (Size:127KB) PP. 191-195
DOI: 10.4236/tel.2013.33032    3,342 Downloads   4,760 Views  

ABSTRACT

We study the information structure implied by models in which the asset price is always risky and there are no arbitrage opportunities. Using the martingale representation of Harrison and Kreps [1], a claim takes its value from the stream of discounted expected payments. Equivalently, a pricing-kernel is sufficient to value the payment stream. If a price process is always risky, then either the payment or the discount factor must also be continually risky. This observation substantially complicates the valuation of contingent claims. Many classical option pricing formulas abstract from both risky dividends and risky discount rates. In order to value contingent claims, one of the assumptions must be abandoned.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Cite this paper

J. Berkowitz, "On the Internal Consistency of the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model," Theoretical Economics Letters, Vol. 3 No. 3, 2013, pp. 191-195. doi: 10.4236/tel.2013.33032.

References

[1] J. M. Harrison and D. M. Kreps, “Martingales and Arbitrage in Multiperiod Securities Markets,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 20, No. 3, 1979, pp. 381-408. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(79)90043-7
[2] F. Black and M. Scholes, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81, No. 3, 1973, pp. 637-659. doi:10.1086/260062
[3] R. C. Merton, “The Theory of Rational Option Pricing,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 4, No. 1, 1973, pp. 141-183. doi:10.2307/3003143
[4] A. Melino and S. Turnbull, “Pricing Foreign Currency Options with Stochastic Volatility,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 45, No. 1-2, 1990, pp. 239-265. doi:10.1016/0304-4076(90)90100-8
[5] S. Heston, “A Closed-Form Solution for Optoins with Stochastic Volatilityi with Applications to Bond and Currency Options,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 6, No. 2, 1993, pp. 327-344. doi:10.1093/rfs/6.2.327
[6] J. C. Cox, J. E. Ingersoll and S. A. Ross, “A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” Econometrica, Vol. 53, No. 2, 1985, pp. 385-408. doi:10.2307/1911242
[7] D. Heath, R. Jarrow and A. Morton, “Bond Pricing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: A New Methodology for Contingent Claims Valuation,” Econometrica, Vol. 60, No. 1, 1992, pp. 77-106. doi:10.2307/2951677
[8] J. M. Harrison and S. Pliska, “Martingales and Stochastic Integrals in the Theory of Continuous Trading,” Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, Vol. 11, No. 3, 1981, pp. 215-260. doi:10.1016/0304-4149(81)90026-0
[9] J. C. Cox and M. Rubinstein, “Options Markets,” Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, 1985.
[10] M. J. Brennan and E. S. Schwartz, “Finite Difference Methods and Jump Processes Arising in the Pricing of Contingent Claims: A Synthesis,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 13, No. 3, 1978, pp. 461-474. doi:10.2307/2330152
[11] J. C. Cox, S. A. Ross and M. Rubinstein, “Options Pricing: A Simplified Approach,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 7, No. 3, 1979, pp. 229-263. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(79)90015-1
[12] J. D. Duffie and P. Protter, “From Discrete to Continuous Time Finance: Weak Convergence of the Financial Gain Process,” Stanford University, Stanford, 1988.
[13] H. He, “Convergence from Discrete to Continuous Time Contingent Claim Prices,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 3, No. 4, 1990, pp. 523-546. doi:10.1093/rfs/3.4.523

  
comments powered by Disqus

Copyright © 2018 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.