[1]
|
J. Williamson, “The Evolution of Global Labour Markets since 1830: Background Evidence and Hypotheses,” Explorations in Economic History, Vol. 32, No. 2, 1995, pp. 141- 196. HHdoi:org/10.1006/exeh.1995.1006
|
[2]
|
P. Krugman, “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, No. 3, 1991, pp. 483-499. HHdoi:org/10.1086/261763
|
[3]
|
M. Fujita, P. Krugman and T. Mori, “On the Evolution of Hierarchical Urban Systems,” European Economic Review, Vol. 43, No. 2, 1999, pp. 209-251.
HHdoi:org/10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00066-X
|
[4]
|
D. Levine and S. Modica, “Anti-Malthus: Evolution, Population, and the Maximization of Free Resources,” 2011 (Forthcoming).
|
[5]
|
J. Hirshleifer, “The Dark Side of the Force: Economic Foundations of Conflict Theory,” Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2001.
|
[6]
|
P. Krugman, “The Self-Organizing Economy,” Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, 1996.
|
[7]
|
R. Axtel, “Zip distribution of US firm sizes,” Science, Vol. 293, No. 5536, 2001, pp. 1818-1820.
HHdoi:org/10.1126/science.1062081
|
[8]
|
F. Hashemi, “A Dynamic Model of Size Distribution of Firms Applied to U.S. Biotechnology and Trucking Industries,” Small Business Economics, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2003, pp. 27-36. HHdoi:org/10.1023/A:1024433203253
|
[9]
|
R. Lucas, “Trade and the Diffusion of the Industrial Re- volution,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2009, pp. 1-25. HHdoi:org/10.1257/mac.1.1.1
|
[10]
|
R. Barro and X. Sala-i-Martin, “Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 2, 1997, p. 126.
HHdoi:org/10.1023/A:1009746629269
|
[11]
|
D. Fudenberg and D. Levine, “Learning and Equilibrium,” Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 1, 2009, pp. 385-419. HHdoi:org/10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.142930
|
[12]
|
D. Levine, “Neuroeconomics,” 2011 (Forthcoming).
|
[13]
|
A. Alchian, “Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 58, 1950, pp. 211-221. HHdoi:org/10.1086/256940
|
[14]
|
J. Hirshleifer, “Economics from a Biological Viewpoint,” Journal of Law & Economics, Vol. 20, 1977, pp. 1-52.
HHdoi:org/10.1086/466891
|
[15]
|
J. Hirshleifer, “Competition, Cooperation, and Conflict in Economics and Biology,” American Economic Review, Vol. 68, 1978, pp. 238-243.
|
[16]
|
D. Levine, “Is Behavioral Economics Doomed? The Ordinary versus the Extraordinary. Open Book Publishers,” 2009 (Forthcoming).
|
[17]
|
F. Hashemi, “An Evolutionary Model of the Size Distribution of Firms,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol. 10, No. 5, 2000, pp. 507-521.
HHdoi:org/10.1007/s001910000048
|
[18]
|
M-O. Hongler, R. Filliger and P. Blanchard, “Soluble Models for Dynamics Driven by a Super-Diffusive Noise,” Physica, 2006, pp. 301-315.
|
[19]
|
M-O. Hongler, H. Soner and L. Streit, “Stochastic Control for a Class of Random Evolution Models,” Applied Mathematics and Optimization, Vol. 49, 2004, pp. 113- 121.
|
[20]
|
O. Besson and G. de Montmollin, “Space-Time Integrated Least Squares: A Time-Marching Approach,” International Journal for Numerical Methods in Fluids, Vol. 44, No. 5, 2004, pp. 525-543. HHdoi:org/10.1002/fld.655
|
[21]
|
A. Toda, “Income Dynamics with a Stationary Double Pareto Distribution,” Physical Review, Vol. 83, 2011, pp. 1-4.
|
[22]
|
F. Hashemi, "East Asian Economic Growth-An Evolutionary Perspective", Journal of Service Science and Management 2011, 4, 280.
|
[23]
|
J. Williamson, "Globalization, Labor Markets and Policy Backlash in the Past", Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 12, No. 4, 1998, pp. 51-72.
|