[1]
|
R. Simmons, “Election of Local Prosecutors,” ElectionLaw@Moritz, moritzlaw.osu.edu/electionlaw/. 2004.
|
[2]
|
S.W. Perry, “Prosecutors in State Courts,” United States Department of Justice, 2005.
|
[3]
|
R. F. Wright, “How Prosecutor Elections Fail Us,” Ohio State Journal of Criminal Law, Wake Forest University, Vol. 6, 2009, pp. 649-660.
|
[4]
|
S. C. Gordon and G. A. Huber, “Citizen Oversight and the Electoral Incentives of Criminal Prosecutors,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 46, No. 2, 2002, pp. 334-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3088380
|
[5]
|
W. M. Landes, “An Economic Analysis of the Courts,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 4, No. 1, 1971, pp. 61-108. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/466704
|
[6]
|
G. M. Grossman and M. L. Katz, “Plea Bargaining and Social Welfare,” American Economic Review, Vol. 73, No. 4, 1983, pp. 749-757.
|
[7]
|
D. Bjerk, “On the Role of Plea Bargaining and the Distribution of Sentences in the Absence of Judicial System Frictions,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 28, No. 1, 2008, pp. 1-7.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.irle.2007.12.005
|
[8]
|
S. Baker and C. Mezzetti, “Prosecutorial Resources, Plea Bargaining, and the Decision to Go to Trial,” Journal of. Law Economics and Organization, Vol. 17, No. 1, 2001, pp. 149-167. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/jleo/17.1.149
|
[9]
|
D. Bjerk, “Guilt Shall Not Escape or Innocence Suffer? The Limits of Plea Bargaining When Defendant Guilt Is Uncertain,” American Law Economics Review, Vol. 9, No. 2, 2007, pp. 305-329.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/aler/ahm010
|
[10]
|
J. F. Reinganum, “Plea Bargaining and Prosecutorial Discretion,” American Economic Review, Vol. 78, No. 4, 1988, pp. 713-728.
|
[11]
|
J. F. Reinganum, “Sentence Guidelines, Judicial Discretion, and Plea Bargaining,” RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 31, No. 1, 2000, pp. 62-81.
|
[12]
|
G. L. Priest and B. Klein, “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 13, No. 1, 1984, pp. 1-55.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/467732
|
[13]
|
S. Shavell, “Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 11, No. 1, 1982, pp. 55-81.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/467692
|
[14]
|
L. A. Bebchuk, “Litigation and Settlement under Imperfect Information,” RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 15, No. 3, 1984, pp. 404-415.
|
[15]
|
L. A. Bebchuk, “Suing Solely to Extract a Settlement Offer,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 17, No. 2, 1988 pp. 437-450.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/468136
|
[16]
|
A. Farmer and P. Pecorino, “Pretrial Negotiations with Asymmetric Information on Risk Preferences,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 14, No. 3, 1994, pp. 273-281.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0144-8188(94)90043-4
|
[17]
|
A. Farmer and P. Pecorino, “Pretrial Bargaining with Self-Serving Bias and Asymmetric Information,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 48, No. 2, 2002, pp. 163-176.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(01)00236-0
|
[18]
|
L. Ancelot and P. Delacote, “Prosecutor and Lawyers in Plea Bargaining with Complete Information,” Economics Bulletin, Vol. 29, No. 3, 2009, pp. 1925-1932.
|
[19]
|
E. Rasmusen, M. Raghav and M. Ramseyer, “Convictions versus Conviction Rates: The Prosecutor’s Choice,” American Law and Economics Review, Vol. 11, No. 1, 2009, pp. 47-78. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/aler/ahp007
|
[20]
|
S. Bandyopadhyay and B. McCannon, “The Effect of the Election of Prosecutors on Criminal Trials,” Working Paper, 2010.
|
[21]
|
R. T. Boylan, “What Do Prosecutors Maximize? Evidence from Careers of US Attorneys,” American Law Economics Review, Vol. 7, No. 2, 2005, pp. 379-402.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/aler/ahi016
|
[22]
|
R. T. Boylan and C. Long, “Salaries, Plea Rates, and the Career Objectives of Federal Prosecutors,” Journal of. Law and Economics, Vol. 48, No. 2, 2005, pp. 27-51.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/429854
|