A Predictive Functional Regression Model for Asset Return

Abstract

Since many of predictive financial variables are highly persistent and non-stationary, it is challenging econometrically to explore the predictability of asset returns. Predictability issues are generally addressed in parametric regressions [1,2] in which rates of asset returns are regressed against the lagged values of stochastic explanatory variables, but three limitations stand ahead [3-5]. This paper studies a predictive functional regression model for asset returns, which takes account of endogeneity and integrated or nearly integrated explanatory variables. The regression function is expressed in terms of distribution of the vector of the observable variables. Estimators are nonlinear functionals of a kernel estimator for the distribution of the observable variables [6]. We find that the estimators for the distribution of the unobservable random terms and the nonparametric function are consistent and asymptotically normal. This paper obtains the similar results in many literatures, for example [1-5], but in different method.

Share and Cite:

X. Dai, H. Li and Y. Wang, "A Predictive Functional Regression Model for Asset Return," Journal of Mathematical Finance, Vol. 3 No. 2, 2013, pp. 307-311. doi: 10.4236/jmf.2013.32030.

1. Introduction

People routinely examine the predictability problem, for example, the mutual fund performance, the conditional capital asset pricing, and the optimal asset allocations. For the predictability of stock returns, various lagged financial variables are used, for example, the log dividend-price ratio, the log earning-price ratio, the log book-to-market ratio, the dividend yield, the term spread, default premium, and the interest rates [3]. Since many of the predictive financial variables are highly persistent and even non-stationary, it is challenging econometrically to explore the predictability of asset returns.

Predictability issues are generally addressed in parametric regressions in which rates of returns are regressed against the lagged values of stochastic explanatory variables. In predictive linear structure model [1,2], excess stock return is the predictable variable at time t, innovations are independently and identically distributed bivariate normal and the log dividend-price ratio is a financial variable at time, which is modelled by an AR(1) model.

There are three limitations. At first, two innovations are unfortunately correlated in real applications [3,4]. The second difficulty arises from the unknown parameter for financial variable regression, for stationary case, see [4,5,7,8], for unit root or integrated, see [9-11], and for local-to-unity or nearly integrated, see [3,12-16]. The third difficulty comes from the instability of the predictive regression model. It concluded from many evidences on the dividend and earnings yield and the sample from the second half of the 1990s that the coefficients should change over time, see, for example [4,5,7,17-19].

In finite samples, the ordinary least squares estimate of the slope coefficient and its standard errors are substantially biased if explanatory variable is highly persistent, not really exogenous, and even non-stationary, see [20]. To avoid over-rejecting the null of non-predictability, some improvements arise, such as the first order biascorrection estimator [2], the two-stage least squares estimator [8], and the conservative bias-adjusted estimator [21], but the instability difficulty was kept silent. To deal with this issue, some predictive regression models were analyzed, for example, excess return predictive regression model on international equity indices [4], equity return predictive regression model [5] with random coefficients generated from a unit root process, asset regression model with varying coefficients [22]. A predictive functional regression model has not touched, though not only interesting in its applications to finance and economics, but also enriching the econometric theory.

The rest of this paper runs as follows. Section 2 proposes basic functional regression model. Section 3 is for nonparametric estimation. Section 4 derives the consistency for the proposed estimator. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Basic Model

We propose a functional regression model to capture the stability of asset returns. It is well known that a nonlinear function would better to characterize dynamic relationship between the stock return and the related financial variables, the two innovations may have a time dependent nonlinear relationship, and the log dividend-price ratio, is a integrated or nearly integrated process [3, 22]. Our model runs as follows.

(1)

(2)

where innovation is exogenous.

To remove the endogeneity, we project onto by, which is strictly increasing in and is uncorrelated with and. See, for example, [23] for endogenous variable. Thus the model becomes

(3)

(4)

The function f can be estimated once function h is estimated due to the strict increasing of with respect to and the Equation (4). Indeed if the functions f and g are linear, the model reduces to [22].

3. Nonparametric Estimation

Once parametric structures are not specified for the functions h in the economic model, the function h is nonadditive in. If the function is additive in unobservable random term, one can interpret this added unobservable random term as being a function of the observable and other unobservable variables, which is hard to estimate this function of the observable and unobservable variables. Here we estimate a nonparametric function h, not necessarily additive.

To estimate the regression function h in the basic model (3), we will derive its expression in terms of the distribution of the vector of the observable variables. Once the unknown regression function is expressed in terms of the distribution of, we will derive its nonparametric estimator for the unknown regression function by substituting the distribution of the observable variables. Though any type of nonparametric estimator for this distribution can be used, we present here the details and asymptotic properties for the case in which the conditional cumulative distributed functions are estimated by the method of kernels. To express the unknown function in terms of the distribution of the observable variables, we need the following assumptions [24].

Assumption 1 is independent of and, and.

Assumption 2 For all values of and, the function h is strictly increasing in.

Assumption 1 guarantees that the distribution of is the same for all values of and. Assumption 2 guarantees that the distribution of can be obtained from the conditional distribution of given and.

Theorem 3 Under Assumptions 1 and 2, the mapping between the unknown regression function h and, the distribution of the observable variables is given by

(5)

for all with.

Proof.

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

According to the theorem above, the following four cases hold.

Lemma 4 (Case 1) For all and some with,

(10)

and Assumptions 1 and 2 hold. Then

(11)

(12)

Lemma 5 (Case 2) For all and some with, and such that and,

(13)

(14)

and Assumptions 1 and 2 hold. Then

(15)

(16)

Lemma 6 (Case 3) For some unknown function, all and some, some, and some such that, and

(17)

(18)

Assumptions 1 and 2 hold, and for all, is strictly increasing. Then, for,

(19)

(20)

Lemma 7 (Case 4) For some unknown function, all and some, some, and some such that, and

(21)

(22)

Assumptions 1 and 2 hold, and for all, is strictly increasing. Then, for,

(23)

(24)

Let denote the data, and, respectively, the joint probability distribution function and cumulative distribution function of, and, respectively, their kernel estimators, and and the kernel estimators of the conditional probability distribution function and cumulative distribution function of given and. Then, according to [6], for all,

(25)

(26)

(27)

(28)

where is a kernel function and is the bandwidth. Hence, for case 1,

(29)

for case 2,

(30)

for case 3,

(31)

for case 4,

(32)

4. Consistency

The consistency and asymptotic normality of the estimator of the marginal or conditional distribution of will follow from the consistency and asymptotic normality of the kernel estimator for the conditional distribution of y given x and. In particular, the asymptotic properties for each of the estimators for the distribution of given above can be derived from Theorem 13 after substituting the corresponding values of y, x, and. For this result, we need following assumptions.

Assumption 8 The sequence is independently identically distributed.

Assumption 9 has compact support and it is continuously differentiable on up to the order for some.

Assumption 10 The kernel function is differentiable of order, the derivatives of K of order are Lipschitz, vanishes outside a compact set, integrates to 1, and is of order where.

Assumption 11 As and, , , , and .

Assumption 12.

Assumptions 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12 for are similar to Assumptions in [24] for.

Theorem 13 Let denote the kernel estimator for the conditional distribution of Y conditional on x and evaluated at. Assumptions 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12 hold. Then, for and,

(33)

in probability, and

(34)

in distribution, where

(35)

Proof. It is the case for in the Theorem 1 in [24] in their notations when is not an argument.

Theorem 13 states that converges to in the supremum norm, and is asymptotically normal with mean and variance equal to

.

To study the asymptotic properties of the estimator for the unknown function h, notice that Equation (3), the estimator for the unknown regression function h can be obtained by substituting the true conditional distributions of Y by their kernel estimators, the consistency and asymptotic normality of the estimator of h will follow from the consistency and asymptotic normality of the functional, , of the kernel estimator for the distribution of. For this result, one more assumption is required as follows.

Assumption 14 The vectors and have at least one coordinate in common, and the values and are different at one such coordinate;,; and there exist such that,.

Assumption 14 is the Assumption if in their notations.

Theorem 15 Assumptions 8, 9, 10, 11 and 14 hold for and. Let,. Then,

(36)

in probability, and

(37)

in distribution, where

(38)

Proof. It is the case for of the Theorem 2 in [24] in their notations when X0 is not an argument.

Theorem 15 implies that is consistent and asymptotically normal with mean and asymptotic variance equal to

(39)

5. Conclusions

This paper studied a predictive regression model which includes the state variable of NI(1) or I(1) and allows endogeneity, where nonlinear regression function is not necessarily additive in unobservable random terms.

We develop a nonparametric method for estimating the functional regression and find that the estimators for the distribution of the unobservable random terms and the nonparametric function are consistent and asymptotically normal. The estimators are nonlinear functionals of a kernel estimator for the distribution of the observable variables. However, the model specification or stationary is not discussed here.

More investigations are worth for the predictive application of this functional regression model due to its importance in various applications in economics and finance. For example, we here keep silent of mixing of and in the context of nonparametric functional predication, though a time-varying coefficient model is valid in [22].

6. Acknowledgement

This project was sponsored by the Scientific Research Foundation for the Returned Overseas Chinese Scholars, State Education Ministry ([2010]609), and the Science Research Foundation, Hubei Provincial Department of Education, P. R. China (D20111508) respectively.

NOTES

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] N. G. Mankiw and M. Shapiro, “Do We Reject Too Often? Small Sample Properties of Tests of Rational Expectation models,” Economics Letters, Vol. 20, 1986, pp. 139-145.
[2] R. Stambaugh, “Bias in Regressions with Lagged Stochastic Regressors,” Working Paper, University of Chicago, 1986.
[3] J. Campbell and M. Yogo, “Efficient Tests of Stock Return Predictability,” Journal of Financial Econometrics, Vol. 81, No. 1, 2006, pp. 27-60. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.05.008
[4] B. S. Paye and A. Timmermann, “Instability of Return Prediction Models,” Journal of Empirical Finance, Vol. 13, No. 3, 2006, pp. 274-315. doi:10.1016/j.jempfin.2005.11.001
[5] T. Dangl and M. Halling, “Predictive Regressions with Time-Varying Coefficients,” Working Paper, School of Business, University of Utah, 2007.
[6] E. A. Nadaraya, “Some New Estimates for Distribution Functions,” Theory of Probability & Its Applications, Vol. 9, No. 3, 1964, pp. 497-500. doi:10.1137/1109069
[7] L. M. Viceira, “Testing for Structural Change in the Predictability of Asset Returns,” Manuscript, Harvard University, 1997.
[8] Y. Amihud and C. Hurvich, “Predictive Regression: A Reduced-Bias Estimation Method,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 39, No. 4, 2004, pp. 813-841. doi:10.1017/S0022109000003227
[9] J. Y. Park and S. B. Hahn, “Cointegrating Regressions with Time Varying Coefficients,” Econometric Theory, Vol. 15, 1999, pp. 664-703. doi:10.1017/S0266466699155026
[10] Y. Chang and E. Martinez-Chombo, “Electricity Demand Analysis Using Cointegration and Error-Correction Models with Time Varying Parameters: The Mexican Case,” Working Paper, Texas A. M. University, 2003.
[11] Z. Cai, Q. Li and J. Y. Park, “Functional-Coefficient Models for Nonstationary Time Series Data,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 2, 2006, pp. 101-113.
[12] G. Elliott and J. H. Stock, “Inference in Time Series Regression When the Order of Integration of a Regressor Is Unknown,” Econometric Theory, Vol. 10, No. 3-4, 1994, pp. 672-700. doi:10.1017/S0266466600008720
[13] C. L. Cavanagh, G. Elliott and J. H. Stock, “Inference in Models with Nearly Integrated Regressors,” Econometric Theory, Vol. 11, No. 5, 1995, pp. 1131-1147. doi:10.1017/S0266466600009981
[14] W. Torous, R. Valkanov and S. Yan, “On Predicting Stock Returns with Nearly Integrated Explanatory Variables,” Journal of Business, Vol. 77, No. 4, 2004, pp. 937-966. doi:10.1086/422634
[15] C. Polk, S. Thompson and T. Vuolteenaho, “Cross-Sectional Forecasts of the Equity Premium,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 81, No. 1, 2006, pp. 101-141. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.03.013
[16] B. Rossi, “Expectation Hypothesis Tests and Predictive Regressions at Long Horizons,” Econometrics Journal, Vol. 10, No. 3, 2007, pp. 1-26. doi:10.1111/j.1368-423X.2007.00222.x
[17] M. Lettau and S. Ludvigsson, “Consumption, Aggregate Wealth, and Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 56, No. 3, 2001, pp. 815-849. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00347
[18] A. Goyal and I. Welch, “Predicting the Equity Premium with Dividend Ratios, Management Science, Vol. 49, No. 5, 2003, pp. 639-654. doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.5.639.15149
[19] A. Ang and G. Bekaert, “Stock Return Predictability: Is It There?” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 20, No. 3, 2007, pp. 651-707. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhl021
[20] C. R. Nelson and M. J. Kim, “Predictable Stock Returns: The Role of Small Sample Bias,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 2, 1993, pp. 641-661. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1993.tb04731.x
[21] J. Lewellen, “Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 74, No. 2, 2004, pp. 209-235. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2002.11.002
[22] Z. Cai and Y. Wang, “Instability of Predictability of Asset Returns,” Working Paper, University of North Carolina at Charlotte, 2009.
[23] A. Torgovitsky, “Identification of Nonseparable Models with General Instruments,” Working Paper, Yale University, 2011.
[24] R. L. Matzkin, “Nonparametric Estimation of Nonadditive Random Functions,” Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 5, 2003, pp. 1339-1375. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00452

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.