Growth Theory and Endogenous Human Capital Development: A Contribution to the Theory of Complex Systems

Abstract

As economic phenomena become increasingly complex, the demands on models to reflect this complexity also increase. Economic growth, for example, which depends on a variety of factors, is such a complex phenomenon. Especially the relevance of human capital development for modern service societies is a significant growth factor. This is, however, considered only in few discussions. In order to represent such complex phenomena, adequate models are needed that go beyond linear approaches. This paper points out that models from the dynamic system theories are well suited to illustrate human capital as a factor of economic growth.

Share and Cite:

Liening, A. (2013) Growth Theory and Endogenous Human Capital Development: A Contribution to the Theory of Complex Systems. Theoretical Economics Letters, 3, 96-104. doi: 10.4236/tel.2013.32016.

1. Introduction

The theory of complex systems can be considered a comparatively young scientific explanatory approach. To an increasing degree, this approach has also been incorporated into economics as a means to better understand order patterns created by free market systems.

von Hayek does not consider order as the result of planning. Rather, he postulates a constructivist error [1] and posits that order is paradoxical and due to an absolute misjudgment of these relations, as we frequently and consciously plan in the modern society because it has become so complex. Furthermore, he argues that we can only achieve an order of such complexity if we do not manage it according to a plan, which is, with the help of instructions, but aim to form a spontaneous order based on general rules instead.

Following von Hayek, such an order cannot be analyzed adequately with the help of frequently applied mechanistic models that are based on lineal1 cause-andeffect chains, which are predictable for this reason.

The development of the economic system as a whole or in particular domains, such as the business sector, is not characterized by fluent transitions. In fact, discontinuities, jump discontinuities and turbulences occur. Thus, economy and economy related subareas can be understood as non-linear, dynamic systems. It is in this context that complex systems are discussed.

To model complex developments that occur in reality, exogenic dysfunctions or random variables are traditionally used. Eventually, abnormal and non-continuous developments are analyzed with the help of methods that only appear applicable for lineal conditions or continuous processes. For a long time, economics was subordinate to the influence of a mechanistic world view, which applied, for example, to models whose trajectories, when tending toward the equilibrium, seemed to be predictable and tangible with the help of partial analyses.

However, in a society that increases in complexity, many economic explanatory approaches based on this world view are not particularly persuasive. Therefore, it is of particular importance to conduct research into new methods in the field of complex dynamic systems.

In many cases, the economic reality is much more difficult and complex than suggested by linear models2. For instance, it is not possible to explain self-organizing processes far from equilibrium with the help of linear views3.

The engagement of nonlinear, complex systems might play a decisive role in searching for an expansion of the economic toolbox, making it possible to represent a wide range of economic behavioral patterns and explanatory approaches. Using this approach, complexity can be described, analyzed and understood, whereas when applying traditional statistical methods, attempts to understand and analyze complexity fail entirely.

Non-linearity, feedback, irreversibility, self-organization and complexity are keywords in this approach whose subcategories can be subsumed under the key phrase “theory of complex systems”. In addition to the theory of self-organization, which is also called synergetics, one must mention Chaos Theory, a theory primarily concerned with questions of origination and analysis of complex order patterns.

Within the scope of its popular scientific upswing in the 1990s, Chaos Theory became the theory of a new homogeneous world explanation or world transfiguration4. Thus, advocates of Chaos Theory attempted to find chaos in the structures of remote galaxies or ascending wads of smoke of a cigarette, whereas opponents of the theory argued that chaos exists only in computer simulations and that there is no real-life application of the theory.

It is true that the possibility of researching chaos with connected order patterns in complex systems has not been imaginable until the development of modern computer technology. The multitude of calculations and the different types of visualization of complex structures were previously unrealizable. Consequently, it should not be astonishing that this theory gained momentum, particularly in the early 1990s.

However, the euphoria that accompanied the Chaos Theory subsided, and the number of popular scientific new publications decreased.

Simultaneously, the number of scientific publications that attempted to transfer important aspects of Chaos Theory to other areas of science increased. Economics has not been excluded, as one expects a better approach to economic reality from Chaos Theory than the neoclassical paradigm can render5.

As Chaos Theory is concerned with open dissipative dynamic systems, growth theory, an important sector of economics, assumes a degree of importance in this context. In the framework of growth theory, dynamization, feedback processes and non-linearity play decisive roles with respect to complexity.

Therefore, in the current article, (endogenous) growth theory shall be considered exemplary6. Throughout the 1970s, it was argued that the “limits of growth” [18] and zero growth were demanded by certain parts of society, but today, there is a considerable awareness that without economic growth, neither advancement nor maintenance of the status quo is possible7. Thus, the relevance of human capital for modern service societies is increasingly recognized without the existence of adequate illustrations in the numerous considerations on growth theory.

This paper contributes to the literature by presenting the dynamic progression of economic growth in terms of the theory of complex systems and introducing the possibility of integrating the importance of human capital into this dynamic progression.

2. The Old Growth Theory

In contrast to post-Keynesian models, the neoclassical Solow model can be referred to as a culmination of the old growth theory. In this neoclassical model, it is implied that there is only one production sector, one good, no foreign countries and no governmental activities. Accordingly, it is like the other growth models, as it has very restrictive assumptions8.

The production function takes precedent in the neoclassical growth theory and is the central neoclassical instrument for theoretical analysis. The production function describes the connection between input and output such that the input consists of two factors of production: labor and capital. Accordingly, the production function can generally be specified in the following manner:, where symbolizes the output [14].

If one considers the production function as a simplification, not twobut one-dimensionally, by considering the output per worker, the following equation, under certain conditions (constant returns to scale), is derived from

or.

Here, the output per worker is symbolized by, and the capital per worker is symbolized by. Expanded by the possibility of technical advancement, one obtains, where is the work efficiency. Then, is the capital intensity for. We define capital intensity as the capital per capita and work efficiency.

An essential result of this theory can be seen in the case of a given saving ratio and identity of economic saving and investment where the long term growth rate of an economy is determined by the growth rate of the population as well as the growth rate of average labor productivity and technical advancement.

The parameters that influence long-term growth (such as population growth and technical advancement) are given exogenously in this model. This also applies for the rate of investment, which in this case—and this is criticized frequently—has no enduring effect on the longterm growth. However, it must be emphasizes that all relevant parameters that guarantee enduring growth are considered exogenously in this context, thus acting as external inferences.

3. The New Growth Theory

3.1. Transition to the New Theory

The relatively unsatisfactory approach, which interprets long-term growth as an exogenous shock, can be modified in such a way that a more realistic model emerges, whose growth determinants are based on the concept of growth as a self-organizing process. The objective must be to specify a model that does not solely denote growth processes by fluent transitions, but a model that allows discontinuities, eruptive changes and turbulences. Only by this means can an economy be regarded as a non-linear, dynamic or complex system. The new growth theory results from these and numerous other considerations.

3.2. Relevance of the Formation of Human Capital and the Entrepreneurial Spirit

In an economy such as Germany, in which almost no natural resources exist, high-quality research and development results play an important role. To obtain such results, highly trained employees are required. Therefore, human capital is an essential and central factor of modern economies9. Human capital will be considered as a production factor, which comprises the abilities, skills and knowledge being internalized by humans during their life span.

On the basis of Romer’s view, the neoclassical production function is to be expanded by a factor that includes this aspect. This, then, results in the fact that human capital in the growth model is endogenized. In this endogenization lies the new quality of growth theory, which can also be referred to as endogenous growth theory.

Thus, the assumption of an exogenously given technical advancement is neutralized. Whereas the neoclassical growth theory assumes that technical and scientific achievements are given factors, the new growth theory asserts to endogenize every important factor.

Accordingly,

(1)

and

10,     (2)

where saving rate, depreciation rate, population growth rate, technological advancement, and

.

is the Cobb-Douglas production function, with as a level parameter and as a parameter of substitution. is the capital (monetary capital and capital equipment) dependent on time t, capital is considered capital per capita or takes the work efficiency per efficiency unit into account such that

. Here, is dependent on investments minus depreciations

plus capital intensity of the past period. In turn, this term is dependent on the exogenously given population growth and the exogenously given technological advancement. Parameter represents the factor by which the work efficiency changes, which, among other things, depends on the standard of knowledge of the labor force.

Based on a technological level, technological advancement increases by the factor, that is,

.

For, analogously,

.

Thus, the following result for technological advancement after periods is. That is, in every period, the technological advancement changes by the factor. If one acts on the assumption of capital intensity, that is, the quotient of capital and work,

, for a certain period, then one apparently obtains the following result for such that as considered above.

The population growth rate has demonstrated similar effects on the capital intensity as technological advancement.

Lucas [21] emphasizes two effects that result from the integration of the development of human capital into an economic growth model. The first effect describes how the human capital levels affect current production, while the second effect considers the way how the accumulation of human capital is affected by the current time allocation.

To integrate these two effects into the model, one therefore assumes that the rate of change of knowledge and competencies is dynamic and depends on the capital accumulation.

The function of human capital is given by

, (3)

with

. (4)

Here, it is assumed that the change of human capital is always positive from a certain income per worker onward and that, over the course of time; it increases according to the law of diminishing returns with the monetary capital and the capital equipment or, more precisely, per efficiency unit (Figure 1).

In this example, , , and in the production function, and are fixed values.

It is plausible to assume that the human capital will stagnate in the medium term when one falls below the assumed minimum of income per worker. The assumption that in the case of a low income, knowledge stagnates instead of decreases is consistent with the pre-

Figure 1. Endogenous growth of human capital according to the law of diminishing returns.

conception held by Romer11.

Overall, on one hand, the possibility of an increased per capita income can grow with increased human capital, increased standards of knowledge and increased levels of competence. On the other hand, an increased per capita income can effectuate the possibility of an increased standard of knowledge and level of competence. Therefore, the individual utility can be interpreted from both directions—education or income.

However, it is not simple to apply this individual situation to the economy as a whole. Let us assume that neither innovations nor technological changes have occurred in the last 100 years. The population would still use carriages to drive through the country and sail ships to cross the oceans. One could enhance the creation of human capital by allowing greater parts of society access to higher education, or one could accelerate the (physical) capital accumulation by producing more sailing ships and carriages. At some point, however, it would be necessary to realize that the economic utility would be only marginal if one additional high school graduate drove one additional carriage [22].

In other words, if one considers the situation from an economic point of view, it becomes obvious that increased human capital does not inherently result in increased economic income advancement. Rather, it is the innovation, creativity, inventive talent and entrepreneurship, as confirmed by Schumpeter [23], which increases human capital and results in a higher standard of living, which is expressed in per capita income12.

Therefore, it is implicitly assumed in the model that between human capital and monetary capital/capital equipment per capita, existing a transmission effect, which can be characterized by terms such as innovation and entrepreneurship.

Ultimately, we derive the following formula for capital intensity:

, (5)

where represents the human capital function.

In the context of the correspondent formation of competence for the development and support of such an effect, it is referred to as entrepreneurship education13. Apart from a competence orientation, the importance of a basis of values should be considered when entrepreneurs or intrapreneurs are educated or further their education. Education in the form of entrepreneurship education furthers economic creativity, responsibility, decision-making ability and independence, as well as the ability to take responsibility for others. In doing so, one should focus on self-organized learning that is inspiring and combined with construction. With the help of methods that activate the learners, this will bring forth judgment competence, decision-making competence, skills and abilities [28]. This could possibly positively intensify the transmission effect. A first illustration of the new growth model is shown in Figure 2.

Here, the saving rate amounts to 40%, i.e.,. For simplification of the analysis, the population growth rate is 0%, i.e.,. The depreciation rate is. In the human capital function, we have and. In the production function, the level parameter is, and the substitution parameter is assumed to be. The reason for this can be found in the previous remarks on the neoclassical model. In addition, it should be annotated that a change of the saving rate can explain a short-term change of the economic growth at the most, but in no case can endure growth be explained. In the original neoclassical model, particularly the exogenously defined population growth and the exogenously given technological advancement could explain enduring growth. In contrast to the neoclassical Solow model, in this model, technological advancement is implicitly explained by the endogenous function for the formation of human capital.

The parameters are chosen accordingly such that ceteris paribus of the endogenously defined formation of human capital, with its transmission effect, comes into

Figure 2. Double cycle attractor for the capital intensity function k(t + 1) in the growth model with endogenous formation of human capital.

question as a cause for enduring growth.

For very low values of capital intensity, that is, money capital and capital equipment per capita or per efficiency unit, the development of human capital stagnates, resulting in the uninterrupted growth of money and capital equipment efficiency, which is measured in efficiency units. For that, it must be presumed that the per capita capital can be found, as in the initial situation, below the steady state in the growth equilibrium14. If the critical point, the minimum income necessary for an increase in knowledge and level of competence, is reached, the human capital begins to grow according to the law of diminishing returns as the work efficiency increases via the transmission effect. Initially, this results in a decline of the capital and capital equipment efficiency.

With the given parameter constellation, it becomes apparent that at a certain basic value of capital intensity a balance is reached, which displays a double cycle. This results from the fact that the critical value is undershot repeatedly at the current parameter constellation, which stagnate the standard of knowledge and level of competence. This leads to a short-term increase in capital and capital equipment intensity, as henceforth, the work efficiency is lower than before. This short-term increase, however, causes the critical value to be exceeded and human capital to grow. Finally, an increase in work efficiency occurs together with a short-term decrease of capital and capital equipment intensity.

This clarifies that the growth effect caused by the endogenous explanation of the accumulation of human capital can by no means result in a constant increase of the gross national product. Rather, fluctuations arise, which, as in the aforementioned parameter constellation, can lead to constant oscillations. The next illustration (Figure 3) demonstrates this process with regard to the development of capital intensity in chronological sequence.

At this point, it should be noted that the endogenization of the standard of knowledge and the level of competence can also have, in addition to a regular progression as described previously, an irregular money capital and capital equipment-per-capita development as a result.

In the following bifurcation diagram the capital intensity, , is presented in relation to the substitution parameter of the production function (Figure 4).

This parameter indicates how strongly the production factor labor is when substituted by the production factor capital (money capital and capital equipment) in the production function. It thus becomes obvious that in the case of increasing values of the substitution parameter of the production function, the development of capital intensity is not stable but instead is interrupted repeatedly by phases of irregular development15.

The bifurcation diagram shows that at approximately and, attractor areas are situated, which are likely described as chaotic due to their struc-

Figure 3. Cyclic development of capital intensity in the growth model with endogenous formation of human capital.

Figure 4. Bifurcation diagram for the growth model with endogenous formation of human capital.

ture. Figure 5 shows one of these strange attractors at, and the development of capital per efficiency unit is presented.

The typical characteristic of strange attractors is the range in which the capital intensity moves. However, the precise position is not definable.

Figure 6 shows the just elucidated situation over a specific period.

Irregular fluctuations that do not suggest a regular pattern are plainly visible.

A more precise analysis, by means of a calculation of Lyapunov exponents16 for several -values, supports the assumption that chaos develops over a specific period. The Lyapunov exponent indicates how the trajectories of two proximate initial values develop in relation to each other. If the Lyapunov exponent is positive, both trajectories exponentially and strongly drift apart. In other words, the butterfly effect completely develops; that is, minimal changes in the initial conditions lead to enormous differences in the results.

Figure 7 presents a diagram showing the money capital and capital equipment per capita development in the

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] F. A. von Hayek, “Die AnmaBung von Wissen,” Mohr-Siebeck, Tübingen, 1996.
[2] A. Liening, “Econoplexity: The Breakdown of the Traditional Mechanistic Worldview, the Development of Complexity Sciences and the Pretence of Knowledge in Economics,” Modern Economy, Vol. 4, No. 4, 2013, pp. 305-319.
[3] P. Nijkamp and J. Poot, “Lessons from Nonlinear Dynamic Economics,” Springer, New York, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York, 1993.
[4] R.-A. Dana and L. Montrucchio, “Dynamic Complexity in Duopoly Games,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 40, No. 1, 1986, pp. 40-56. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(86)90006-2
[5] F. Bestenreiner, “Der Phantastische Spiegel,” Moos u. Partner, München, 1989.
[6] B. B. Mandelbrot and R. L. Hudson, “Misbehavior of Markets,” Basic Books, New York, 2004.
[7] F. Trosky, “Heterogene Erwartungen auf dem Geldmarkt,” Duncker & Humblot, Berlin, 2005.
[8] T. Bussow, “Chaostheorie und Unternehmenssteuerung: Konstruktionen zur Modellgestützten Entscheidungsvorbereitung,” Deutscher Universitats-Verlag, Wiesbaden, 2003.
[9] G. Zehetner, “Anwendungen der Chaostheorie in der Betriebswirtschaftslehre,” Facultas, Wien, 2003.
[10] T. Puu, “Attractors, Bifurcations & Chaos: Nonlinear Phenomena in Economics,” Springer, New York, 2003. doi:10.1007/978-3-540-24699-2
[11] G. Antinolfi, T. Keister and K. Shell, “Growth Dynamics and Returns to Scale: Bifurcation Analysis,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 96, No. 1-2, 2001, pp. 70-96. doi:10.1006/jeth.1999.2632
[12] T. Mitra and K. Nishimura, “Discounting and Long-Run Behavior: Global Bifurcation Analysis of a Family of Dynamical Systems,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 96, No. 1-2, 2001, pp. 256-293. doi:10.1006/jeth.2000.2642
[13] L. Gardini, I. Sushko and A. K. Naimzada, “Growing through Chaotic Intervals,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 143, No. 1, 2008, pp. 541-557. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2008.03.005
[14] R. M. Solow, “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 70, No. 1, 1956, pp. 65-94. doi:10.2307/1884513
[15] P. M. Romer, “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94, No. 5, 1986, pp. 1002-1037. doi:10.1086/261420
[16] R. Deneckere and S. Pelikan, “Competitive Chaos,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 40, No. 1, 1986, pp. 13-25. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(86)90004-9
[17] M. Otaki, “A Keynesian Endogenous Growth Theory with a Rigorous Microeconomic Foundation,” Theoretical Economics Letters, Vol. 2, No. 4, 2012, pp. 365-368. doi:10.4236/tel.2012.24067
[18] D. H. Meadows, C. O. Rome and P. Associates, “The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project on the Predicament of Mankind,” Universe Books, New York, 1972.
[19] H. Siebert, “Jenseits des Sozialen Marktes,” Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, München, 2005.
[20] R. H. Day, “Irregular Growth Cycles,” American Economic Review, Vol. 72, No. 3, 1982, pp. 406-414.
[21] R. E. Lucas, “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22, No. 1, 1988, pp. 3-42. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
[22] A. Liening, “Okonomische Chaostheorie,” H. May, Ed., Lexikon der Okonomischen Bildung, Wien, 1996.
[23] J. Schumpeter, “Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung,” Duncker & Humblot, Berlin, 1934.
[24] B. Ziesemer, “Eine Kurze Geschichte der Okonomischen Unvernunft: Die Deutsche Wirtschaftspolitik und das Gesetz der Unbeabsichtigten Folgen,” Campus, Frankfurt, New York, 2007.
[25] R. Cantillon, “Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en General,” Institut National d’ètudes Démographique, Paris, 1952.
[26] R. B. Emmett, “The Economist and the Entrepreneur: Modernist Impulses in Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit,” History of Political Economy, Vol. 31, No. 1, 1999, pp. 29-52.
[27] H. Mandl and J. Hense, “Lernen Unternehmerisch Denken: Das Projekt Tatfunk,” München, 2004.
[28] A. Liening, “Komplexe Systeme zwischen Ordnung und Chaos,” Lit, Münster, Hamburg, London, 1999.
[29] M. Schonhofer, “Chaotic Learning Equilibria,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 89, No. 1, 1999, pp. 1-20. doi:10.1006/jeth.1999.2509
[30] R. M. Solow, “Growth Theory: An Exposition,” Oxford University Press, New York, Oxford, 1987.

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.