Keywords:Order Statistics; Semimartingales; Local Times; Arbitrage
1. Introduction
The theory of asset pricing and its fundamental theorem were initiated in the Arrow-Debreu model, the Black and Scholes formula, and the Cox and Ross model. They have now been formalized in a general framework by Harrison and Kreps [1], Harrison and Pliska [2], and Kreps [3] according to the no arbitrage principle. In the classical setting, the market is assumed to be frictionless i.e. a no arbitrage dynamic price process is a martingale under a probability measure equivalent to the reference probability measure.
However, real financial markets are not frictionless, and so an important literature on pricing under transaction costs and liquidity risk has appeared. See [4,]">5] and references therein. In these papers the bid-ask spreads are explained by transaction costs. Jouini and Kallal in []">5] in an axiomatic approach in continuous time assigned to financial assets a dynamic ask price process (respectively, a dynamic bid price process). They proved that the absence of arbitrage opportunities is equivalent to the existence of a frictionless arbitrage-free process lying between the bid and the ask processes, i.e., a process which could be transformed into a martingale under a well-chosen probability measure. The bid-ask spread in this setting can be interpreted as transaction costs or as the result of entering buy and sell orders.
Taking into account both transaction costs and liquidity risk, Bion-Nadal in [4] changed the assumption of sublinearity of ask price (respectively, superlinearity of bid price) made in []">5] to that of convexity (respectively, concavity) of the ask (respectively, bid) price. This assumption combined with the time-consistency property for dynamic prices allowed her to generalize the result of Jouini and Kallal []">5]. She proved that the “no free lunch” condition for a time-consistent dynamic pricing procedure [TCPP] is equivalent to the existence of an equivalent probability measure
that transforms a process between the bid and ask processes of any financial instrument into a martingale. See also Cherny [6] regarding the characterization of non-existence of arbitrage opportunities for stock prices constructed from bid and ask processes.
In recent years, a pricing theory has also appeared taking inspiration from the theory of risk measures. First to investigate in a static setting were Carr, Geman, and Madan [7] and Föllmer and Schied [8]. The point of view of pricing via risk measures was also considered in a dynamic way using backward stochastic differential equations [BSDE] by El Karoui and Quenez [9], El Karoui, Peng, and Quenez [10], and Peng [11,12]. This theory soon became a useful tool for formulating many problems in mathematical finance, in particular for the study of pricing and hedging contingent claims [10]. Moreover, the BSDE point of view gave a simple formulation of more general recursive utilities and their properties, as initiated by Duffie and Epstein (1992) in their [stochastic differential] formulation of recursive utility [10].
In the past, in real financial markets, the load of providing liquidity was given to market makers, specialists, and brokers, who trade only when they expect to make profits. Such profits are the price that investors and other traders pay, in order to execute their orders when they want to trade. To ensure steady trading, the market makers sell to buyers and buy from sellers, and get compensated by the so-called bid-ask spread. The most common price for referencing stocks is the last trade price. At any given moment, in a sufficiently liquid market there is a best or highest “bid” price, from someone who wants to buy the stock and there is a best or lowest “ask” price, from someone who wants to sell the stock. The best bid price
and best ask (or best offer) price
are the highest buying price and the lowest selling price at any time
of trading.
In the present work, we consider models of financial markets in which all parties involved (buyers, sellers) find incentives to participate. Our framework is different from the existing approach (see [4,]">5] and references therein) where the authors assume some properties (sublinearity, convexity, etc.) on the ask (respectively, bid) price function in order to define a dynamic ask (respectively, bid). Rather, we assume that the different bid and ask prices are given. Then the question we address is how to model the “best bid” (respectively, the “best ask”) price process with the intention to obtain the stock price dynamics.
The assumption that the bid and ask processes are described by (continuous) semimartingales in our special setting entails that the stock price admits arbitrage opportunities. Further, it turns out that the price process possesses the Markov property, if the bid and ask are Brownian motion or Ornstein-Uhlenbeck type, or more generally Feller processes. Note that our results are obtained without assuming arbitrage opportunities.
This paper is also related with [13] where the authors explore market situations where a large trader causes the existence of arbitrage opportunities for small traders in complete markets. The arbitrage opportunities considered are “hidden” which means that they are almost not observable to the small traders, or to scientists studying markets because they occur on time sets of Lebesgue measure zero.
The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 studies the Markovian property of the processes, while Sections 4 and 5 are devoted to the study of completeness, arbitrage and (insider) hedging on a market driven by such processes.
2. The Model
Let
(where
denotes transpose) be a n-dimensional standard Brownian motion on a filtered probability space
.
Suppose bid and ask price processes
, which are modeled by continuous semimartingales
(1)
Here we consider the following model for bid and ask prices. See Figure 1.
The evolution of the stock price process
is based on
. Denote by
the Best Bid and Ask(t) the Best Ask at time t. Then
is the lowest price that a day trader seller is willing to accept for a stock at that time and Ask(t) is the highest price that a day trader buyer is willing to pay for that stock at any particular point in time. Let us define the processes
and
. Further set

where we use the convention that
and
. Then
and
can be modeled as
(2)
and
(3)
Given
and
, the market makers will agree on a stock price within the Bid/Ask spread, that is
(4)
where
is a stochastic process such that
One could choose e.g.,
for a function
or
for a function
.
For convenience, we will from now on assume that
, that is
(5)
3. Markovian Property of Processes R, T and S
For convenience, let us briefly discuss the Markovian property of the processes
and
in some particular cases. The two cases considered here are the cases when the process 
are Brownian motions or Ornstein-Uhlenbeck processes. Let us first have on the definition of semimartingales rank processes.
Definition 3.1 Let
be continuous semimartingales. For
, the k-th rank process of
is defined by
(6)
where
and
.
Note that, according to Definition 3.1, for
,
(7)
so that at any given time, the values of the rank processes represent the values of the original processes arranged in descending order (i.e. the (reverse) order statistics).
Using Definition 3.1, we get
(8)
3.1. The Brownian Motion Case
Here we assume that the processes
are independent Brownian motions.
Proposition 3.2 The process
possesses the Markov property with respect to the filtration
.
Proof. Let
be a one-dimensional Brownian motion. We first prove that
is a Markov process. Define the process

Then
is a two dimensional Feller process.
Let
. One observes that
is a continuous and open map. Thus is follows from [14] (Remark 1, p. 327) that
is a Feller process, too.
The latter argument also applies to the n-dimensional case, that is
is a Feller process. Since

is a continuous and open map we conclude that
is a Feller process. 
Proposition 3.3 The process
possesses Markov property with respect to the filtration
.
Proof. See the proof of Proposition 3.2. 
Corollary 3.4 The process
possesses Markov property with respect to the filtration
.
Proof. The process
defined by
for all
is a Markov process as sum of two Markov processes. 
3.2. The Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Case
Here we assume that the process
is an n-dimensional Ornstein-Uhlenbeck, that is
(9)
where
and
are parameters. It is clear that an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process is a Feller process. So we obtain Proposition 3.5 The process
and
defined by (8) and (5) possess Markov property.
Proof. The conclusion follows from the proof of Proposition 3.2. 
Remark 3.6 Using continuous and open transformations of Markov processes, the above results can be generalized to the case, when the bid and ask processes are Feller processes. See [14].
4. Further Properties of S(t)
In this Section, we want to use the semimartingale decomposition of our price process
to analyze completeness and arbitrage on market driven by such a process.
We need the following result. See [15] (Proposition 4.1.11). See also [16] for the continuous semimartingales case and [17] for general semimartingales.
Theorem 4.1 Let
be continuous semimartingales of the form (1). For
let
be any predictable process with the property:
(10)
Then the k-th rank processes
, are semimartingales and we have:
(11)
where
is the local time of the semimartingale
at zero, defined by

where
.
For completeness, we give the proof of the proposition.
Proof. We find that
(12)
where we used the property
. It follows,

We note the fact
(13)
We now use the following formula:
(14)
which is valid for non-negative semimartingales
. See, e.g., [15,18]
Then, by applying (14) to
, (12) becomes:

Then proof is completed.
4.1. The Brownian Motion Case
If
are
independent Brownian motions, the evolution of
and
follows from Theorem 4.1.
Corollary 4.2 Let the processes
and
be given by Equation (8). Then
and
and we have:
(15)
and
(16)
We can rewrite
and
as follows:

where
are continuous local martingales and
are continuous processes of locally bounded variation given by:
(17)
(18)
(19)
(20)
The following corollary gives the semimartingale decomposition satisfied by the process
.
Corollary 4.3 Assume that the process
is given by (5). Then one can write 
where
and
, and we have:
(21)
In order to price options with respect to
, one should ensure that
does not admit arbitrage possibilities and the natural question which arises at this point is the following: Can we find an equivalent probability measure
such that,
is a
-sigma martingale? Since the process
is continuous, we can reformulate the question as: Can we find an equivalent probability measure
such that,
is a
local martingale1?
We first give the following useful remark; See [19] (Theorem 1).
Remark 4.4 Let
be a continuous semimartingale on a filtered probability space
. Let
. A necessary condition for the existence of an equivalent martingale measure is that
.
Consequence 4.5 Since local time is singular, we observe that the total variation of the bounded variation part in 21 cannot be absolutely continuous with respect to the quadratic variation of the martingale. It follows that, the set of equivalent martingale measures is empty, and thus, such a market contains arbitrage opportunities.
4.2. (In)complete Market with Hidden Arbitrage
In this Section, we consider a model with
, denoting a stochastic process modeling the price of a risky asset, and
denotes the value of a risk free money market account. We assume a given filtered probability space
, where
satisfies the “usual hypothesis”. In such a market, a trading strategy
is self-financing if
is predictable,
is optional, and
(22)
for all
. For simplicity, we let
and
(thus the interest rate
), so that
, and (22) becomes

Definition 4.6 (See [13])
• We call a random variable
a contingent claim. Further, a contingent claim
is said to be
-redundant if, for a probability measure
, there exists a self-financing strategy
such that
(23)
where
is the value of the portfolio.
• A market
is
-complete if every
is
-redundant.
Define the process
as follows
(24)
Then the following theorem is immediate from [13] (Theorem 3.2).
Theorem 4.7 Suppose that there exists a unique probability measure
equivalent to
such that
is a
-local martingale. Then, the market
is
-complete.
Proof. Omitted. 
Proposition 4.8 Suppose that
. Then, there exists no unique martingale measure
such that
is a
-local martingale.
Proof. From (24), we observe that
is a
-martingale. Let us construct another equivalent martingale measure
For this purpose, assume without loss of generality that
and
are given by

and

Now define the process
as

where

with
(25)
One finds that
for all
. Let us define the equivalent measure
with respect to a density process
given by

Here,
denotes the Doléans-Dade exponential of the martingale
defined by

Then, it follows from the Girsanov-Meyer theorem (see [20]) that
has a
-semimartingale decomposition with a bounded variation part given by
We have that

Since
, it follows that

Thus
is a
-martingale. Since
is also a martingale measure with
, the result follows. 
Remark 4.9 In the case
(a single Bid/Ask), the market becomes complete since the process
, defined by Equation (25) in the proof is equal to
. Therefore the unique martingale measure is
.
We can then deduce the following theorem on our process
.
Theorem 4.10 Suppose that
and
are given by (21) and (24), respectively. Then
• For
(a single Bid/Ask), the market
is
-complete and admits the arbitrage opportunity (26).
• For
(more than a single Bid/Ask), the market
is incomplete and arbitrage exists.
Proof. From Theorem 4.8, we know that the market is
-complete for
and incomplete for
. Let
such that
is a
-local martingale. For
, let us construct an arbitrage strategy. Let
(26)
where
denotes the
by
support of the (random) measure
; that is, for fixed
it is the smallest closed set in
such that
does not charge its complement. (Compare with the proof of Proposition 4.8.) Let

Assume without loss of generality that
. Then, by Theorem 4.7, there exists a self financing strategy
such that
However, from (26), we also have
Moreover, we have
, by construction of the process
.
Hence,
which is an arbitrage opportunity. 
Remark 4.11 We do not make the assumption that we are working in an arbitrage free market, rather, we define the notion of redundancy (see [13] Definition 2.1), which in some sense is equivalent to the notion of replication with the difference that, replication is on a arbitrage free setting.
5. Pricing and Insider Trading with Respect to S(t)
In this Section, we discuss a framework introduced in [21], which enables us pricing of contingent claims with respect to the price process
of the previous sections. We even consider the case of insider trading, that is, the case of an investor, who has access to insider information. To this end, we need some notions.
We consider a market driven by the stock price process
on a filtered probability space
. We assume that, the decisions of the trader are based on market information given by the filtration
with
for all
being a fixed terminal time. In this context an insider strategy is represented by an
-adapted process
and we interpret all anticipating integrals as the forward integral; See, for e.g., [22,23] for more details. In such a market, a natural tool to describe the self-financing portfolio is the forward integral of an integrand process
with respect to an integrator
denoted by
; See [23]. The following definitions and concepts are consistent with those given in [21].
Definition 5.1 A self-financing portfolio is a pair
, where
is the initial value of the portfolio and
is a
-adapted and
-forward integrable process specifying the number of shares of held in the portfolio. The market value process
of such a portfolio at time
, is given by
(27)
while
constitutes the number of shares of the less risky asset held.
5.1.
-Martingales
Now, we briefly review the definition of
-martingales which generalizes the concept of a martingale. We refer to [21] for more information about this notion. Throughout this Section,
will be a real linear space of measurable processes indexed by
with paths which are bounded on each compact interval of
.
Definition 5.2 A process
is said to be a
-martingale, if every
in
is
-improperly forward integrable and
(28)
Definition 5.3 A process
is said to be
-semimartingale if it can be written as the sum of an
-martingale
and a bounded variation process
, with
.
• Remark 5.4
• Let
be a continuous
-martingale with
belonging to
, then, the quadratic variation of 
exists improperly. In fact, if
exists improperly, then one can show that
exists improperly and
.
• Let
a continuous square integrable martingale with respect to some filtration
. Suppose that every process in
is the restriction to
of a process
which is
-adapted. Moreover, suppose that its paths are left continuous with right limits and
. Then
is an
-martingale.
5.2. Completeness and Arbitrage:
-Martingale Measures
The subsequent definitions and notions are from [21].
Definition 5.5 Let
be a self-financing portfolio in
, which is
-improperly forward integrable and
its wealth process. Then
is an
-arbitrage if
exists almost surely,
and 
Definition 5.6 If there is no
-arbitrage, the market is said to be
-arbitrage free.
Definition 5.7 A probability measure
is called a
-martingale measure if with respect to
the process
is an
-martingale according to Definition 5.2.
We need need the following assumption. See [21].
Assumption 5.8 Suppose that for all
in
the following condition holds. Then
is
-improperly forward integrable and
(29)
The proof of the following proposition can be found in [21].
Proposition 5.9 Under Assumption 5.8, if there exists an
-martingale measure
, the market is
-arbitrage free.
Definition 5.10 A contingent claim is an
-measurable random variable. Let
be the set of all contingent claims the investor is interested in.
• Definition 5.11
• A contingent claim
is called
-attainable if there exists a self-financing trading portfolio
with
in
, which is
-improperly forward integrable, and whose terminal portfolio value coincides with
, i.e., 
Such a portfolio strategy
is called a replicating or hedging portfolio for
and
is the replication price for
.
• A
-arbitrage free market is called
-complete if every contingent claim in
is attainable.
Assumption 5.12 For every
-measurable random variable
, and
in
the process
, belongs to
.
Proposition 5.13 Suppose that the market is
-arbitrage free, and that Assumption 5.8 holds. Then the replication price of an attainable contingent claim is unique.
Proof. Let
be a given measure equivalent to
. For such a
, let
be a set of all strategies (
- adapted) such that (28) in Definition 5.2 is satisfied. Then, it follows from Proposition 5.9 that the market
in Section 4.2 is
-arbitrage free. 
Next, we shall discuss attainability of claims in connection with a concrete set
of trading strategies.
5.3. Hedging with Respect to S(t)
In this Section, we want to determine hedging strategies for a certain class of European options with respect to the price process
of Section 4.2. Let us now assume that
(a single Bid/Ask). Then, the price process
is the sum of a Wiener process and a continuous process with zero quadratic variation; moreoverwe have that
, where
is given by (25). We can derive the following proposition which is similar to [21] (Proposition 5.29).
Proposition 5.14 Let
be a function in
of polynomial growth. Suppose that there exist
of class
which is a solution of the following Cauchy problem
(30)
Set

Then
is a self-financing portfolio replicating the contingent claim
.
In particular,
is
-complete, where
is given by

and
by all claims as stated in this Proposition.
Proof. The proof is a direct consequence of Itô’s Lemma for forward integrals. See [21] (Proposition 5.29).
6. Conclusion
In this paper, assuming that the dynamics of the bid and ask prices are given by Itô processes, we derive the stochastic differential equation satisfied by the “best bid” and the “best ask” from which we get the dynamic of the middle (stock) price. The evolution of the latter is given by a semimartingale, whose final variation part, is not absolute continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure. We then show that, such a market admits a hidden arbitrage opportunity and compute the arbitrage strategy. We also discuss the notion of (insider) hedging in this market.
NOTES
1In fact since S is continuous and since all continuous sigma martingales are in fact local martingales, we only need to concern ourselves with local martingales