Real Options Assessment in the Time-Fractional Heston Model with Jump and Inertia ()
1. Introduction
Real options may be classified into different groups which the most common types are: option to expand, option to abandon, option to wait, option to switch, and option to contract.
Pricing financial derivatives is one of the most extensively researched subjects in financial mathematics, spanning back to the classical Black-Scholes-Merton model [1] [2]. However, these models frequently presume continuous price processes and Markovian dynamics, which leave little room for real-world features such as memory effects, abrupt market jumps, and inertia in volatility behavior.
Recent advancements include:
1) Fractional dynamics: Alós et al. [3] investigated fractional stochastic volatility models which include memory effects but exclude market jumps.
2) Jump-diffusion models: Benth and Pircalabu [4] incorporated jumps in asset price dynamics but omitted fractional-time derivatives.
3) Time-fractional PDEs: Zhang et al. [5] assessed fractional Black-Scholes models ignoring stochastic volatility.
This paper inserts fractional-time derivatives [6], jumps, and inertia within the Heston model [7], shifting it as a time-fractional HJB equation. This enables a robust mathematical evaluation of real option prices underneath these convoluted patterns.
2. The Time-Fractional Heston Model with Jumps and Inertia
Model Formulation
The time-fractional Heston model is governed by the following PDE:
(1)
where:
(2)
with:
is the log-price, and
is the stochastic variance.
is the volatility of volatility,
is the rate of mean reversion,
is the long-run variance, and
is the risk-free rate.
models the jump intensity and
represents the jump magnitude.
is the Caputo fractional derivative:
(3)
3. Main Results
3.1. Existence and Uniqueness of Viscosity Solutions [8]
Theorem 3.1 (Existence of Viscosity Solutions) Let
be the initial condition. There exists a viscosity solution
to the time-fractional HJB equation:
(4)
where:
(5)
Proof. We introduce a small regularization parameter
and consider the regularized equation:
(6)
where
.
Using the Caputo fractional derivative:
(7)
The regularized equation becomes:
(8)
Next, multiply the regularized equation by
and integrate over
:
(9)
Respectively, for the First term (integration by parts):
(10)
(11)
(12)
Combining all terms:
(13)
Simplifying:
(14)
Furthermore,
From the a priori estimates,
is uniformly bounded in
. By the Rellich-Kondrachov compactness theorem, there exists a subsequence
strongly in
as
. Passing to the limit in Equation (8):
(15)
Finally,
To confirm
as a viscosity solution: For test functions
, if
has a local maximum, we verify:
(16)
(17)
Thus,
is a viscosity solution of the time-fractional HJB equation.
Corollary 3.1 (Uniqueness) The viscosity solution of (77) is unique under the comparison principle:
(18)
Proof. Define
. Then
satisfies:
(19)
By the monotonicity of
with respect to
, we have:
(20)
where
is the partial derivative of
with respect to
.
Substitute this inequality into the equation for
:
(21)
Assume
achieves its maximum at
. At this point, the following conditions hold:
(22)
From the viscosity inequality for
and
, we have:
(23)
Subtract these two inequalities:
(24)
By the monotonicity of
, we replace the second term:
(25)
At
, where
achieves its maximum:
(26)
Thus:
(27)
Since
by assumption on
, it follows that:
(28)
Because
achieves its maximum at
, and
, we conclude:
(29)
Now repeat the argument for
, where
achieves its maximum. The same steps show:
(30)
Therefore:
(31)
Thus:
(32)
3.2. Higher-Order Regularity
Proposition 3.1 (Higher-Order Regularity) If
, then the viscosity solution
.
Proof. Let first determine the Spatial Regularity Estimate (x-derivatives)
The time-fractional Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation is given by:
(33)
where:
Differentiate (33) twice with respect to
:
(34)
where:
The leading order term
satisfies the elliptic regularity estimate:
(35)
Using the Sobolev embedding theorem:
where
(log-price
), choose
large enough to satisfy:
Thus:
Next, let determine the Temporal Regularity Estimate (t-derivatives)
The Caputo fractional derivative is expressed using the Duhamel principle:
(36)
Since
from Step 1:
The fractional temporal estimate for the Caputo derivative gives:
(37)
From (36) and the regularity of
, we obtain:
Combining the spatial regularity
and temporal regularity
, we conclude:
3.3. Topological Entropy
Nonlinear Extension and Topological Entropy
We extend the system to a nonlinear regime, where the Denjoy-type theorem guarantees the continuity of invariant measures. The topological entropy
is computed as:
(38)
Quantifying the system’s complexity and market unpredictability.
Theorem 3.2 For the nonlinear system:
(39)
There exists a continuous invariant measure
, and the system satisfies the Denjoy-type theorem.
Proof. The equation is:
(40)
where:
(41)
The fractional derivative is in the Caputo sense:
(42)
Next, the regularize the problem:
(43)
Multiply through by
and integrate over a domain
:
(44)
Moreover, substituting the Caputo derivative:
(45)
Using Fubini’s theorem:
(46)
Else, let expand the Hamiltonian term:
(47)
Integrate the second-order term by parts:
(48)
Similarly, for the mean-reversion term:
(49)
Finally, the jump term becomes:
(50)
Taking the expectation:
(51)
Combining all terms, we get:
(52)
As
, compactness in
implies:
(53)
Therefore, let define the invariant measure
as:
(54)
Theorem 3.3 (Topological Entropy) The topological entropy
is given by:
where
is the minimum number of
-balls required to cover all trajectories over time
.
Proof. Let define progressively the following: Let
be a solution of the time-fractional Heston model:
(55)
Define the metric on the space of trajectories
as:
(56)
The solution
satisfies:
(57)
For two trajectories
and
, subtract their governing equations:
(58)
Integrating in the Caputo sense, we have:
(59)
Assume
is Lipschitz continuous with constant
:
(60)
Then:
(61)
Applying the fractional Grönwall inequality, we obtain:
(62)
where
is the Mittag-Leffler function:
(63)
For
, the number of
-balls required to cover
satisfies:
(64)
where
depends on
,
, and
. Substituting
into the entropy definition:
(65)
Using the asymptotic form of
, we find:
(66)
Simplifying:
(67)
The topological entropy of the time-fractional Heston model with jumps and inertia is given by:
(68)
Remark 3.1 (Application of Topological entropy to real option assessment and risk management) Consider Equation (1) and assume the trajectory space be equipped with the metric:
(69)
Assuming Lipschitz continuity of
, we easily get
(70)
where
is the Mittag-Leffler function, and
.
The minimal number of
-balls covering the solution space satisfies
(71)
Yielding the topological entropy
(72)
We define the entropy-based risk functional
(73)
Thus, the entropy sensitivity of the solution is
(74)
taking the limits
(75)
Therefore, in the evaluation of real options and in risk management, the entropy
acts as a non-linear, memory-sensitive quantifier of information volatility. It also captures both the diversity and the instability of future scenarios governed by the underlying fractional dynamics of (1).
3.4. Sub-/Super-Martingale Analysis
Recall that the time-fractional Heston model with jumps and inertia is given by:
(76)
where:
and
models inertia.
The Caputo time-fractional derivative is approximated using the Grünwald-Letnikov scheme:
(77)
The finite difference approximation of (76) becomes:
(78)
Reorganizing for
, we obtain:
(79)
Theorem 3.4 (Backward Martingale Convergence) Let
be the finite difference approximation to the time-fractional Heston model (76). Then:
where
is the unique viscosity solution of the time-fractional Heston equation.
Proof. Define:
From (79), we write:
(80)
Conditioning on the filtration
, we have:
(81)
Thus,
is a backward martingale.
Next, taking the square norm:
Summing from
to
:
Since
is uniformly bounded:
Thus:
Let discuss on the
-Convergence Subtract
from
:
(82)
Summing over
:
Thus
is Cauchy in
, and there exists
such that:
Again, from Doob's theorem, the backward martingale
converges almost surely:
Substitute
into the original Equation (76) and verify that it satisfies:
(83)
The uniqueness of viscosity solutions guarantees that
is the unique limit.
3.5. Game Theory and Strategic Decisions
Theorem 3.5 Let
be the value function of the following two-player zero-sum game:
where
and
are stopping times. There exists a Nash equilibrium solution
satisfying Equation (1).
Proof. For Player 1, who seeks to maximize the payoff function:
the associated HJB equation is:
(84)
For Player 2, who seeks to minimize the same payoff:
the corresponding HJB equation is:
(85)
Assume that a single value function
exists such that:
Substitute
into the HJB equations, resulting in:
(86)
The supremum and infimum conditions for controls
and
are given by:
where the operator
is defined as:
(87)
Finally, define a fixed-point operator
acting on
:
(88)
To prove existence:
Start with an initial guess
.
Iteratively compute
for
.
By Banach’s Fixed-Point Theorem, if
is a contraction mapping:
then
as
, where
satisfies:
At equilibrium,
satisfies:
(89)
(90)
Thus, the stopping times
and
achieve the equilibrium payoff:
(91)
An attempt to extend the above theorem to more complex game structures and multiple players is given by the result below:
Corollary 3.2 (Multi-Player Fractional Game Equilibrium) Let
be stopping times in an
-player zero-sum stochastic game with payoff functions
(92)
and assume
. Then there exists an equilibrium profile
, and a common value function
solving the equation
(93)
Sketch of Proof. Define individual value functions:
(94)
First, assume symmetry:
(95)
Then, the HJB equation per player is given by:
(96)
(97)
The compact equation is given by:
(98)
Secondly, consider the following fixed-point operator
(99)
(100)
Using contraction, we have the below property
(101)
Taking
such that
is a contraction.
Therefore,
(102)
By the following sub and supermartingale definition
(103)
We ultimately get the equilibrium payoff
(104)
4. Discussion and Conclusion
4.1. Discussion
This study proposes an integrated methodology for pricing real options utilizing the time-fractional Heston model with jumps and inertia. Both continuous and discrete versions overcomes the flaws of classical stochastic volatility models, mainly their inability to incorporate: Memory effects represented by fractional derivatives, Sudden jumps accounted for by jump processes and inertia modeled as resistance to price changes. The combination of these features into a single unified model enables a more accurate representation of complex financial market dynamics. Specifically:
The time-fractional derivative
(with
) captures long-memory effects and non-locality in time, addressing observed volatility persistence [9].
The jump term
represents discontinuous price movements, which are essential for modeling market shocks [10].
The inertia functional
accounts for real-world resistance to change, reflecting the structural rigidity of illiquid markets.
4.2. Conclusion
We presented an approach for assessing real options under the time-fractional Heston model with jumps and inertia (1) which opens several avenues for further research such as the fact to calibrate the model parameters to multiple assets with correlated volatilities, including the fractional order
, jump intensity
, and inertia terms, using real financial data. The necessity to incorporate machine learning techniques can enhance parameter estimation and volatility prediction. Moreover, investigate the relationship between topological entropy and systemic risk measures can enable to develop early warning systems based on entropy-based indicators to monitor financial market stability. Finally, extending the model to specific industries such as energy, infrastructure, and real estate markets, where investment decisions involve long-term uncertainty, inertia, and memory effects can strengthen the theoretical underpinning and broaden the scope of its application, guaranteeing the model remains relevant under volatile and uncertain market conditions.