Is Agricultural Production Spillover the Rationale behind CAADP Framework? Spatial Panel Model Approach

Abstract

The creation of a union is often rationalized on grounds of moving the equilibrium toward the first best solution whenever independent policies generate spillovers. This arises as a common agenda can significantly reduce the scope of free-riding behavior among member countries. In addition, cross-border externalities arising out of higher levels of market integration entails countries to agree on policy coordination. The present study explores the extent and magnitude of agricultural production spillover that might validate the adoption of a common agriculture agenda among African countries. Overall, our results suggest the presence of positive and significant agricultural production spillover. No evidence of beggar-thy-neighbor or negative spillover policies was found; on average, each country received 2.5 percent growth as a result of spillover. Our results also suggest that convergence dynamics is much stronger when spillover is accounted for, which provides a rationale for a common agenda such as CAADP.

Share and Cite:

J. Ulimwengu and P. Sanyal, "Is Agricultural Production Spillover the Rationale behind CAADP Framework? Spatial Panel Model Approach," Modern Economy, Vol. 4 No. 5, 2013, pp. 391-402. doi: 10.4236/me.2013.45041.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] A. N. Pratt and B. Yu, “An Updated Look at the Recovery of Agricultural Productivity in Sub-Saharan Africa,” IFPRI Discussion Paper No. 787, Washington DC, 2008.
[2] FAO, FAOSTAT Database, 2006. http://faostat3.fao.org/home/index.html
[3] FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations), “Agriculture’s Contributions to Economic and Social Development,” The Electronic Journal of Agricultural and Development Economics, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2004, pp. 1-5.
[4] NEPAD Secretariat, CAADP, “CAADP Country Level Implementation Process,” Concept Note Prepared by the NEPAD Secretariat Based on the Outcome of the NEPAD Implementation Retreat, Pretoria, 24-25 October 2005. http://fsg.afre.msu.edu/mgt/caadp/country_implementation_process_concept_notev21.pdf
[5] H. P. Binswanger-Mkhize and A. F. McCalla, “The Changing Context and Prospects for Agricultural and Rural Development in Africa,” International Fund for Agricultural Development and African Development Bank, Rome and Tunis, 2009.
[6] R. Stringer and P. Pingali, “Agriculture’s Contributions to Economic and Social Development,” Journal of Agricultural and Development Economics, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2004, pp. 1-5.
[7] DFID, “Agriculture and Poverty Reduction: Unlocking the Potential,” DFID Policy Paper, London, 2003.
[8] F. Ellis, “A Livelihoods Approach to Migration and Poverty Reduction,” Paper commissioned by DFID, London, 2003.
[9] M. Fafchamps, F. Teal and J. Toye, “Towards a Growth Strategy for Africa,” Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford, Oxford, 2001.
[10] T. Reardon, J. Bergegué and Escobar, G., “Rural Nonfarm Employment and Incomes in Latin America: Overview and Policy Implications,” World Development, Vol. 29, No. 3, 2001, pp. 395-409. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00112-1
[11] UNECA (United Nations Economic Commission for Africa) Economic Report on Africa, “Accelerating Africa’s Development through Diversification,” Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 2007.
[12] A. Wambo, “Regional Integration in Africa and Its Implications for Rural Development,” UN Economic Commission for Africa Report No. 2, Addis Ababa, 2006.
[13] F. Etro, “International Policy Coordination with Economic Unions,” Harvard University Manuscript, Boston, 2001.
[14] A. D. Janvry and E. Sadoulet, “Agriculture for Development in Africa: Business-as-Usual or New Departures,” Journal of African Economies, Vol. 19, Suppl. 2, 2010, pp. ii7-ii39
[15] A. Dorward, S. Fan, J. Kydd, H. Lofgren, J. Morrison, C. Poulton, N. Rao, L. Smith, H. Tchale, S. Thorat, I. Urey and P. Wobst, “Institutions and Economic Policies for Pro-Poor Agricultural Growth,” DSGD Discussion Paper No. 15, IFPRI and Centre for Development and Poverty Reduction, Washington DC and London, 2004.
[16] J. A. Berdegué, “Cooperating to Compete. Peasant Associative Business Firms in Chile,” Published Doctoral Dissertation, Wageningen University and Research Centre, Department ofSocial Sciences, Communication and Innovation Group, Wageningen, 2001.
[17] K. Felgenhauer and P. Labella, “Global Agro-Food Supply Chain: Is there space for Africa?” In: Turning African Agriculture into a Business: A Reader, OECD Development Center, Paris, 2008.
[18] M. Kherallah, C. Delgado, E. Gabre-Madhin, N. Minot and M. Johnson, “Reforming Agricultural Markets in Africa: Achievements and Challenges,” Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 2002.
[19] T. S. Jayne, J. Govereh, A. Mwanaumo, J. K. Nyoro and A. Chapoto, “False Promise or False Premise? The Experience of Food and Input Market Reform in Eastern and Southern Africa,” World Development Vol. 30, No. 11, 2002, pp. 1967-1985. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00115-8
[20] X. Diao, P. Hazell, D. Resnick and J. Thurlow, “The Role of Agriculture in Development: Implications for Sub-Saharan Africa,” Research Report 153, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC, 2007.
[21] O. Badiane, S. Odjo and J. Ulimwengu, “Emerging Policies and Partnerships under CAADP: Implications for Long-Term Growth, Food Security, and Poverty Reduction,” IFPRI Discussion Paper No. 1145, 2011. http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/ifpridp01145.pdf
[22] A. Alesina, I. Angeloni and F. Etro, “The Political Economy of International Unions,” NBER Working Paper No. 8645, Cambridge, 2001. http://cdi.mecon.gov.ar/biblio/docelec/harvard/hier/1939.pdf
[23] J. P. Lesage and M. M. Fisher, “Spatial Growth Regressions: Model Specification, Estimation and Interpretation,” Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 3, No. 3, 2008, pp. 275-304. doi:10.1080/17421770802353758
[24] R. J. Barro and X. Sala-i-Martin, “Economic Growth Theory,” MIT Press, Cambridge, 1995.
[25] K. O. Fuglie, “Is a Slowdown in Agricultural Productivity Growth Contributing to the Rise in Commodity Prices?” Agricultural Economics, Vol. 39, No. s1, 2008, pp. 431-441. doi:10.1111/j.1574-0862.2008.00349.x
[26] C. L. Delgado, “Agricultural Diversification and Export Promotion in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Food Policy, Vol. 20, No. 3, 1995, pp. 225-243. doi:10.1016/0306-9192(95)00015-7
[27] P. L. Pingali, Y. Bigot and H. P. Binswanger, “Agricultural Mechanization and the Evolution of Farming in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 1987.
[28] G. C. Mrema, D. Baker and D. Kahan, “Agricultural Mechanization in Sub-Saharan Africa: Time for a New Look,” Agricultural Management, Marketing and Finance Occasional Paper 22, Rome, 2008.
[29] J. Robinson, “Essays on the Theory of Employment,” Blackwell, Oxford, 1937.
[30] G. Corsetti and P. Pesenti, “Welfare and Macroeconomic Interdependence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 116, No. 2, 2001, pp. 421-46. doi:10.1162/00335530151144069

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.