Smart Grid and Renewable Energy, 2009, 43–53
Published Online September 2009 (http://www.SciRP.org/journal/sgre/).
1
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments
ABSTRACT
Increasing the proportion of power derived from renewable energy sources is becoming an increasingly important
part of many countries’s strategies to achieve reductions in greenhouse gas emissions. However, renewable energy in-
vestments can often have external costs and benets, which need to be taken into account if socially optimal investments
are to be made. This paper attempts to estimate the magnitude of these external costs and benets for the case of re-
newable technologies in Scotland, a country which has set particularly ambitious targets for expanding renewable en-
ergy. The external effects we consider are those on landscape quality, wildlife and air quality. We also consider the
welfare implications of different investment strategies for employment and electricity prices. The methodology used to
do this is the choice experiment technique. Renewable technologies considered include hydro, on-shore and off-shore
wind power and biomass. Welfare changes for different combinations of impacts associated with different investment
strategies are estimated. We also test for differences in preferences towards these impacts between urban and rural
communities, and between high-and low-income households.
© 2004 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
Keywords: Renewable Energy; External Costs and Benets; Choice Experiments
1. Introduction
Increasing the proportion of power derived from renew-
able energy sources is becoming an increasingly impor-
tant part of many country’s strategies to achieve reduc-
tions in greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. However, re-
newable energy investments can often have external
costs and benets, which need to be taken into account if
socially optimal investments are to be made. This paper
attempts to estimate the magnitude of these external costs
and benets for the case of renewable technologies in
Scotland, a country which has set particularly ambitious
targets for expanding renewable energy. The external
effects we consider are those on landscape quality, wild-
life and air quality. Unlike other papers in the literature,
we do not restrict our investigation to the effects of par-
ticular technologies (such as hydro or wind, Alvarez
Farizo and Hanley, 2002; Hanley and Nevin, 1999), but
consider impacts applicable to a wide range of renewable
technologies. We also consider the welfare implications
of alternative investment strategies for employment and
electricity prices. The methodology used to do this is the
choice experiment (CE) technique. Renewable technolo-
gies considered include hydro, on-shore and off-shore
wind power and biomass. Welfare changes for different
combinations of impacts associated with different in-
vestment strategies are estimated. We also test for dif-
ferences in preferences towards these impacts between
urban and rural communities, and between high and
low-income households.
In what follows, Section 2 sets out some background
detail on energy policy in Scotland. Section 3 provides a
brief overview of the CE method, whilst in Section 4 we
outline the design and conduct of our empirical study.
Section 5 presents results from data analysis, including
the conditional logit models estimated from the CE data.
Section 6 evaluates the welfare effects of alternative in-
vestment strategies in renewables, whilst the nal section
presents some conclusions.
2. Scotland as a Case Study
Scotland has recently started down a new path in how it
generates electricity (ROS, 2002). The Scottish Execu-
tive has set two challenging targets for use of renewable
pow- er sources in the next 20 years:
*
Corresponding author.
Tel.:
+44
141
330
5982;
fax:
+44
141
330
–4940.
E-mail address: arielbergmann@yahoo.com (A. Bergmann).
0301–4215/$ - see front matter © 2004 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2004.08.035
by 2010, 18% of electricity consumed should come
from renewable generation,
by 2020, that portion should rise to 40%.
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments
44
Currently only 10% of the electric energy produced in
Scotland comes from renewable sources such as wind
energy, hydro and waste-to-energy plants. These targets
are thus ambitious, as the potential for large-scale hydro
is close to fully developed, and as wave energy technol-
ogy has not yet been adequately tested on a commercial
scale. The 400% increase in clean electricity production
will have to come from new energy projects and new
technologies. The 2020 goal is three times larger than the
negotiated portion Scotland has committed to as its con-
tribution the UK’s reduced GHG obligation. Denmark,
with a 79% renewable electricity goal by 2030, is the
only European Union member with comparable volun-
tary goals (de Vries et al., 2003).
The major political reasons for promoting renewable
energy are external to Scotland. The UK has accepted a
legally binding target of reducing emissions of a bundle
of GHGs by 12.5% below 1990 emission levels by
2008–2012, as its share of the European Union negoti-
ated target of an 8% reduction in GHGs under the Kyoto
Protocol. The Energy White Paper “Our energy futurec-
reating a low carbon economy”, published in February
2003 by the British Government, includes an even more
ambitious path of reducing CO2 emissions by some 60%
of current levels by 2060 (DTI, 2003). Currently, the UK
Renewables Obligation-a requirement on power supply
companies to meet certain minimum fractions of total
supply from renewables-has set a target of 10.4% by
2010–2011.
The economic reasons for Scotland developing re-
new-ables are multifaceted. The rst reason is that re-
newable energy projects by their very nature should be
highly sustainable. There is minimal or no resource de-
pletion due to the use of renewables technologies, as
compared to gas-, oil- and coal-based energy. Renewable
energy projects, as with traditional fossil fuel projects,
tend to be capital intensive, so the opportunity to develop
and manufacture renewable energy equipment for do-
mestic use and international export exists. In 2001, Ves-
tas, a major manufacturer of wind turbines, announced a
manufacturing facility would be opened in Scotland
(Scottish Executive, 2001), although most capital equip-
ment is currently imported. There is the potential to
transfer some of the job skills learned in the North Sea
oil industry to the marine renewables sector, which in-
cludes tidal, wave, and ocean current power generation
technologies, as the off-shore oil industry declines (a
European Marine Energy Centre (EMEC, 2004) was
opened on Orkney in 2004 to assist in the advancement
of marine energy). Off-shore wind farm development
may need this skilled labour pool. England and Wales
will have a more difcult time building sufcient re-
newables capacity to provide adequate non-fossil fuel
energy that their populations will need to meet domestic
targets (OXERA, 2002). Scotland, on the other hand, has
some of the greatest renewables potential in all of Europe,
and therefore may have sufcient excess supplies to trade
south of the border. Finally, rural areas of Scotland, with
some of the greatest needs for economic development,
will be the location of most all land-based renewable
energy projects (Hassan et al., 2001). These rural com-
munities may well reap benets from these long-term
projects.
A fundamental restructuring of the power industry will
need to be undertaken to achieve these renewable targets.
Since the 1880s in Scotland, as in the rest of the world,
the power industry has been organised with a centralised
hierarchical technological and management structure.
Ever-larger generating facilities based on fossil fuels and
nuclear power, and a unied transmission network to
distribute the electricity over hundreds of miles, were the
model of development. The nature of land-based renew-
able energy projects makes this development style tech-
nically impossible at this time. Current scale economies
dictate that projects like wind farms and biomass genera-
tion plants be 3–5% the size of a traditional 1200 MW
coal-red plant. Even the largest wind farms being plann-
ed today are only 20% of this size. Also, because of the
intermittency problems of renewable sources, greater
quantities (measured by megawatt capacity) of generat-
ing assets are needed because of the lower average usage
of this capacity. Renewable energy projects normally
require large amounts of space to capture the energy in
wind, water or solar radiation in sufcient quantity to be
commercially viable. Dozens of communities in Scotland
will therefore likely be impacted by renewable energy
projects that will need to be constructed to meet the Scot-
tish Executive’s clean energy goals. As noted above,
only 10% of electricity in Scotland is currently generated
from renewable sources, mainly from hydro power sta-
tions (Scottish Executive, 2002b). The biggest current
share of generation (44%) is from nuclear stations: how-
ever, all of these are planned to close by 2023 (NIA,
2003), and no new nuclear plants are likely to be com-
missioned.
The primary policy instrument being utilised by the
Scottish Executive to motivate what is thus a very large
expansion of renewable energy sources is the Renew-
ables Obligation (Scotland) (ROS). The ROS has com-
bined a demand-push legal requirement for renewable
power usage with a supply pull nancial incentive pro-
gramme to reward private industry for constructing and
investing in new renewable energy generation projects.
The ROS compels licensed electricity suppliers to source
specic quantities of eligible renewable energy for sale
to all customers (residential, commercial and industrial),
or face nancial penalties for the shortfall. The associ-
ated increase in electricity costs is shared by all consum-
ers and avoids the free-rider problem (Rose et al., 2002).
The original minimum supply of renewable power by
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments45
retailers, by quantity, was set at 3% for2002–2003, rose
to 4.3% for 2003–2004, and will rise annually to 10.4%
in 2010–2011. During the 18 months since the ROS was
implemented in April 2002, signicant increases in re-
newable generation projects have applied for or are mov-
ing towards application and planning consent. In all,
1500 MW of capacity has sought consent and another
2500 MW of capacity is near requesting consent (BWEA,
2003).
The nancial incentives for private investment in re-
newable power facilities are created by the use of the
renewable obligation certicates (ROCs). Electricity sup-
pliers use these certicates as evidence that the required
percentage of sales is matched with eligible green power
production. The ROCs are traded separately from the
actual electricity being generated and had a market price
of £45–50 per megawatt during the rst year of the ROS.
This money is earned by the renewable power generating
company and represents revenue above the value of the
electricity being sold to the power market. Renewable
power generators earned £63–75 per megawatt of pro-
duction during the 2002–2003 period as compared to
£17–25 per megawatt paid for fossil fuel-powered pro-
duction.
3. The Choice Experiment Method
Renewable energy investments in Scotland are thus ex-
pected to grow rapidly in the near future. These invest-
ments will produce a series of potential impacts on the
environment, price of electricity and employment. Envi-
ronmental impacts will include landscape effects, effects
on wildlife and changes in air pollution (e.g. waste to
energy plants emit air pollution). Exactly what environ-
mental impacts occur, what happens to electricity prices
through changes in cost, and any changes in employment,
will depend on the exact investment mix (e.g. the balance
between on-and off-shore wind farms; the extent of hy-
dro developments). Taken together, environmental ef-
fects, price effects and employment effects can be
thought of as the attributes of a renewable energy strat-
egy. Knowing something about the relative economic
values of these attributes is important if we wish a re-
newables strategy to (i) take some account of public
preferences and (ii) take some account of economic
efciency (benet-cost) concerns. Choice Experiments
are an economic valuation method which enables this
kind of information to be produced.
3.1 The Characteristics Theory of Value
and Random Utility Theory
CEs are based on two fundamental building blocks:
Lancaster’s characteristics theory of value, and random
utility theory (RUT). Lancaster (1966) asserted that the
utility derived from a good comes from the characteris-
tics of that good, not from consumption of the good
itself. Goods normally possess more than one charac-
teristic and these characteristics (or attributes) will be
shared with many other goods (Lancaster, 1966). The
value of a good is then given by the sum of the value of
its characteristics.
RUT is the second building block. RUT says that not
all of the determinants of utility derived by individuals
from their choices is directly observable to the research-
er, but that an indirect determination of preferences is
possible (McFadden, 1974; Manski, 1977). The utility
function for a representative consumer can be decom-
posed into observable and stochastic sections:
,
anan an
UVe
(1)
where Uan is the latent, unobservable utility held by
consumer n for choice alternative a, Van is the systemic
or observable portion of utility that consumer n has for
choice alternative a, and ean is the random or unobserv-
able portion of the utility that consumer n has for choice
alternative a. Research is focussed on a probability func-
tion, dened over the alternatives which an individual
faces, assuming that the individual will try to maximise
their utility (Bennett and Blamey, 2001; Louviere et al.,
2000). This probability is expressed as
(\)[() ()]
nananjn
PaCP VeVe
jn
 (2) aj
for all j options in choice set Cn, a and n are as previ-
ously described, or
(\)[() ()]
nanjnjna
PaCP VVee
n
 (3) aj
To empirically estimate (3), and thus to estimate the
observable parameters of the utility function, assump-
tions are made about the random component of the model.
A typical assumption is that these stochastic components
are independently and identically distributed (IID) with a
Gumbel or Weibull distribution. This leads to the use of
multinomial (sometimes called conditional) logit (MNL)
models to determine the probabilities of choosing a over j
options (Hanley et al., 2001):
exp( )
()
exp( )
a
an jn
j
V
PU UjV

(4) aj
Here, µ is a scale parameter, inversely related to the
standard deviation of the error term and not separately
identiable in a single data set. The implications of this
are that the estimated β values cannot be directly inter-
preted as to their contribution to utility, since they are
confounded with the scale parameter. When using the
MNL model choices must satisfy the independence from
irrelevant alternatives (IIA) property, which means that
the addition or subtraction of any option from the choice
set will not affect relative probability of individual n
choosing any other option (Louviere et al., 2000). Mod-
elling constants known as alternative specic constants
(ASCs) are typically included in the MNL model. The
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments
46
ASC accounts for variations in choices that are not ex-
plained by the attributes or socio-economic variables,
and sometimes for a status quo bias (Ben-Akiva and
Lerman, 1985).
The estimated coefcients of the attributes can be used
to estimate the tradeoffs between the attributes that re-
spondents would be willing to make. The price attribute
can be used in conjunction with the other attributes to
determine the willingness-to-pay of respondents for gains
or losses of attribute levels. This monetary value is call
the “implicit price” or part-worth of the attribute:
nonmarket attribute
part worthmonetaryattribute

(5)
The scaling problem noted above is resolved when
one attribute coefcient is dividing by another, as in
the part-worth equation, since the scale parameter
cancels out.
4. Study Design and Implementation
To meet Scottish Executive targets, hundreds of renew-
able energy projects of all sizes and types of technology
have been proposed. These range from large wind farms
and new hydroelectric schemes that have signicant im-
pacts on the countryside and local communities, to small
changes like the addition of solar panels to rooftops and
district heating plans with impacts that may only be felt
by the immediate residents. This paper’s objective is to
estimate the value of positive and negative impacts aris-
ing from the kind of renewable energy projects that will
be developed over the coming years.
4.1 Designing the Choice Experiment
In any CE, attributes must be chosen which meet a num-
ber of requirements. These are that they are:
relevant to the problem being analysed,
capable of being understood by the sample popula-
tion, and
of applicability to policy analysis.
Identifying the set of attributes and the levels these
take is a key phase in CE design. To this effect, focus
groups were conducted with members of the general pub-
lic (Dewar, 2003). The objective set to each group was to
identify the ‘characteristics’ of ‘green’ electric energy
production that were regarded as ‘good’ or ‘bad’. The
facilitator had each group identify all the types of re-
newable power technologies that they could, and then
discuss the good or bad characteristics of each type of
energy project. Technologies that were identied were:
windmills, hydro schemes (run of river and reservoir),
tidal and wave power, solar (photovoltaic and hot water
panels) geothermal, various types of biomass or waste
combustion like burning municipal solid waste, wood
burning, animal and organic waste, natural gas from
landlls and fermentation of organics. After
identication of the attributes of each technology, the
groups were requested to separate into smaller sections
of two or three persons, and rank these attributes by im-
portance to them. After that exercise, individuals were
asked to indicate their personal choices for which char-
acteristics were most important or of concern to them.
Three characteristics that dominated all others were re-
vealed by the focus groups. One was that renewable en-
ergy projects have a low environmental impact, and
should reduce how we change or pollute the environment.
Another was that the projects be aesthe- tically pleasing.
This characteristic was a little more contentious because
some group members felt that both windmills and reser-
voirs are pleasing to observe, while other members felt
that large man-made structures took away from nature’s
scenic beauty. The nal dominant characteristic was that
wildlife should not be harmed any further and that pro-
jects that improved wildlife should be supported. Other
less signicant characteristics mentioned by individuals
or groups were the creation of jobs, the effect on electric-
ity prices, the abundance and sustainability of the re-
sources, and more localised control and responsibility for
the project.
Five key attributes were then chosen, based on these
focus groups responses, and also on government state-
ments (e.g. Scottish Executive, 2002b) and the literature.
The attributes chosen were:
impacts on the landscape,
impacts on wildlife,
impacts on pollution levels, in particular, air pollu-
tion,
creation of long-term employment opportunities, and
potential increases in electric prices to pay for renew-
able sources.
Once these attributes were determined, a question-
naire was constructed that presented the context of re-
newable energy development in Scotland. The national
commitment by the UK to reduce production of GHGs
was explained. Survey participants were told that the
survey was not concerned with any specic type of re-
newables technology, but with the impacts that could
result from development of any renewable energy re-
source. The ve attributes noted above were described,
with examples being given to clarify each type of impact.
SPSS (VERSION 10.0) was used to select a set of op-
timal choice proles, which were then combined to make
up the choice sets used in the experiment. Table 1 shows
the attributes and levels as used in the nal design. Given
the ve attributes and 17 associated levels, 1800 possible
proles exist, which was an unfeasible number to employ
in the survey. We thus used a fractional factorial design
to reduce this full factorial to 24 proles that could be
used to estimate main effects. This smaller set was also
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments47
Table 1. Attributes and attribute levels
designed for orthogonality, which is a desirable, but not a
required, mathematical characteristic of choice set con-
struction. Twenty different choice sets were thus de-
signed and used in the questionnaire, blocked into sets of
four (that is, each respondent worked there way through
four choice tasks). Combined plans were alternated in the
order in which they appeared as a choice set and the or-
der of the individual plans were alternated between the
rst or second within the choice set. This was done to
avoid any bias from the ordering of choices.
Choice sets were then presented, and the survey par-
ticipant was requested to indicate their preference. Each
set contained three options. Plans A and B were possible
renewable energy projects, each with different attribute
levels. A third option of choosing neither was given. This
‘neither’ option, commonly called the opt-out or status
quo option, stated that there would be no increase in re-
newable energy, that alternative programmes would be
implemented to avoid climate change, and that North Sea
natural gas usage would be expanded to provide for fu-
ture electricity generation. Figure 1 gives an example
choice set. The nal page of the questionnaire was con-
cerned with collecting standard socioeconomic informa-
tion about the participant. Information was requested
about location of household, number of children, em-
ployment in the energy sector, membership in a conser-
vation group, age, household income, education attain-
ment and amount of last electric bill.
Because of budgetary constraints, the design was se-
lected to estimate principal effects only. No secondary
cross-effects can be determined from the choice design
being used. The sample size requirements grow too rap-
idly when cross-effects are to be studied. The question-
naire and accompanying cover letter were then submitted
to a small pretest with regard to their clarity and useful-
ness of the information contained. Feedback from this
process lead to a revised and shortened version of the
cover letter, clarication of some terminology and chan-
ges in how the socio-economic information was re-
quested in the questionnaire. The questionnaire and other
survey materials can be found in Hanley et al. (2004).
4.2 Sample Selection
The sampling frame for this project was the Scottish gen-
eral public. Our sample population was randomly se-
lected from the list of registered voters in eight council
districts of Scotland. The districts are Aberdeenshire,
Highlands and Islands, Western Isles, Edinburgh, Glas-
gow, Stirling, Borders and Dumfries and Galloway. Ap-
proximately 250 names were from Glasgow and Edin-
burgh, 80 from Aberdeenshire and 30–45 names from
each of the other districts.
A mail survey was used due to constraints imposed by
project funding. Some 547 names were selected and
mailed survey packages with a cover letter during the rst
week of September 2003. As an incentive to participate a
£20 prize draw was offered. Three weeks later a follow-up
postcard was mailed to encourage the completion and re-
turn of the survey. By October 2003, 219 households had
returned surveys, a 43% response rate after undeliverables
are considered. Two hundred and eleven surveys were
received in time to be part of the sample set. Eight surveys
were returned too late to be included. Two hundred and
eighty-seven households did not respond. This response
rate is acceptable, and comparable to other studies (Ek,
2002; Hanley et al., 2001) that had response rates ranging
from 44% to 56%, for a survey mailed to the general
population. Mail surveys tend to have the lower response
rates than telephone or face-to-face interviews (Bateman et
al., 2002). The sample group of respondents should also be
tested for any self-selection bias, which could result in a
biased MNL estimates and WTP amounts.
5. Data Analysis
To model the information collected from the question-
Attribute
Description Levels
Landscape
The visual impact of a project is dependent on a
combination of
None, low, moderate,
high
impact
both the size and
location
Wildlife
impact Change in habitat can inuence the amount and diversity of species Slight
improvement,
no impact, slight
harm
Air
pollution
Many types of renewable energy projects create no
additional air
pollution, but some projects do
burn non-fossil fuels. These
projects
produce a very small amount of pollution when compared
to
electricity generated from coal or
natural gas
None, slight
increase
Jobs
All renewable energy projects will create new local
long-term
employment to operate and
maintain the projects.
Temporary
employment increases during the
construction
phase are not
being
considered
1–3, 8–12, 20–25
Price Annual increase in household electric bill resulting from
expansion
of renewable energy projects.
An average household pays £270
a
year (£68 per quarter) for
electricity
£0, £7, £16, £29, £45
Alternate specific
constants
ASC-A Takes value of 1 for Plan A, 0 otherwise. Acts to
represent
variations that cannot be explained by
the
attributes
or
socio-
economic
variables
ASC-B Takes value of 1 for Plan B, 0 otherwise. Acts to
represent
variations that cannot be explained by
the
attributes
or
socio-
economic
variables
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments
48
Figure 1. Example choice set
naire, each choice set has three lines of code that com-
bines the attribute levels, ASCs and socio-economic
variables (Bennett and Blamey, 2001). The data matrix
appeared in the form:
alternative plan A :
,
aaattributessociecon
VASCX Y
 
alternative plan B :
,
bbattributessoci econ
VASCX Y
 
no renewables option : attributessoci econ
Vn XY
, (the
neither=opt-out plan)
where V is the
conditional
indirect utility,
ASCa,b are
the alternative specic constants for each choice
plan,
β
attributes
is a vector of coefcients associated with
the
attributes
X and levels, and
β
socio-econ
is a vector
of
coefcients associated with the socio-economics
descry-
p
tors Y of the
respond
ents.
NLOGIT 3.0/LIMDEP 8.0 econometric software was
used to estimate the MNL model. Attributes were effect
coded, rather than being coded using dummy variables, as
this will provide estimates that are uncorrelated to the in-
tercept of the model (Louviere et al., 2000). Effect coding
means that at least one level of each attribute is not in-
cluded as an identied variable: thus a three-level attribute
generates two variables. The excluded level is coded as
negative one. The attributes levels chosen for exclusion
were the ones hypothesised to have the most negative ef-
fect on environmental amenities. Therefore, the estimated
coefcients for each of the remaining levels indicate the
value respondents placed on the change from the lowest
valued (omitted) level to the level of greater utility. The
omitted levels were: high landscape impact, slight wildlife
harm and slight increase in air pollution. The effect of
these omitted levels on utility is given by the negative of
the sum of the coefcients on all the included levels.
5.1 Descriptive Statistics
Any mail survey has the risk of self-selection bias. Com-
paring the socio-economic information collected on the
211 respondents used in the CE against the statistical
prole of the Scottish population is one test for such a
bias: the null hypothesis that the experiment population
is equal to the national population must be rejected for
bias to be suspected. In our sample, respondent’s income
and location of residence are different from the national
distribution at 10% level. Our sample is thus lower in-
come than the national average, and more rural. These
two descriptors are in fact correlated with each other.
Rejection of the null hypothesis means that the estimated
coefcients and the calculated WTP values may not be
statistically valid representations of the whole Scottish
population.
5.2 Model estimation and results
Results for all 211 respondents from the MNL model are
shown in Table 2. The ‘‘simple’’ model shows results
when only the CE attributes are included in the regres-
sion. The coefcients are interpreted as the parameters of
the indirect utility function, although the fact that they
are confounded with a scale parameter means that one
cannot directly interpret their numerical value (the scale
parameter cancels out when calculating implicit prices or
welfare measures). Coefcient signs show the inuence
of attributes on choice probabilities: here, all attribute
coefcients have the expected signs. The signs of all but
the price attribute are positive, as consumer preference
theory predicts, since these attributes are coded to show
an increase in environmental quality, which should lead
to increased utility. Price is negative and therefore also in
accord with standard economic theory. All of the envi-
ronmental attributes are signicant determinants of utility
at some level: changes in air pollution, landscape effects
and wildlife effects. However, employment creation is
not a signicant attribute.
A series of socio-economic variables were proposed
for inclusion in an ‘‘expanded’’ model based on standard
consumer theory. The Student’s t-test and log-likelihood
tests were then used to determine acceptance or rejection
of each variable. The rejected descriptive variables were:
does the respondent have children, employment in the
energy sector, membership in a conservation group,
amount of last electric bill, age by ve categories and
education by three categories. The covariates used in the
“expanded” model in Table 2 thus show either statistical
signicance or are included on theoretical grounds. Edu-
cation and age are in the former class, while income is
the latter case.
A likelihood ratio test was used to compare the “sim-
ple” and “expanded” models, and rejected the null hy-
pothesis that the parameter values of the two models are
equal at the 95% signicance level. Implicit prices de-
rived from the two models are not statistically different.
Simple visual examination of this is conrmed by the
large overlap of the condence intervals (95% level) of
implicit prices of both models (the delta method was
used to calculate the condence intervals). The adjusted
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments49
Table 2. Multinomial model results
Model Model: expanded model w/covariates Simple model: attributes only
Descriptor Coefcient Implicit
price (£)
(std.
error)
(95% condence
interval) Coefcient Implicit
price (£)
(std.
error)
(95% condence
interval)
Moderate
Landscape
Low 0.29 5.58 (2.99) (0.28–11.44) 0.20 4.07 (2.99) (–1.79–9.93)
Landscape 0.15 2.82 (3.56) (–4.16–9.79) 0.16 3.21 (3.56) (–3.77–10.19)
None
Landscape 0.42* 8.10* (1.94) (4.30–11.90) 0.39* 7.88* (1.94) (4.08–11.68)
None
Wildlife 0.22** 4.24** (2.18) (–0.03–8.51) 0.27* 5.51* (2.18) (1.24–9.78)
Improved
Wildlife 0.63* 11.98* (1.88) (8.30–15.66) 0.50* 10.11* (1.88) (6.43–13.79)
None
Air pollution 0.74* 14.13* (1.88) (10.45–17.81) 0.71* 14.40* (1.88) (10.72–18.08)
Employment
Price
ASCA
0.02
–0.05*
2.80*
0.32 (0.22)
(–0.11–0.66)
(0.0065)
0.01
–0.05*
2.96*
0.23 (0.22) (–0.20–0.66)
(0.0058)
ASCB 2.73* 2.80*
IncomeA –0.01
IncomeB2
Higher
educationA
–0.01
0.99*
Higher
educationB2 0.85*
Under age 40-A 1.06**
Under age 40-B 0.88***
Log-likelihood –434 –509
No. of
observations 739 836
Pseudo-R2 0.31 0.29
*Signicant at 1% level, **signicant at 5% level and ***signicant at 10% level. Bold indicates monetary implicit
values.
Table 3. Implicit prices from the model with covariates
Landscape
impact Households are WTP £8.10 to decrease high impact landscape changes to having no landscape impact
Wildlife impact WTP of £4.24 to change a slight increase in harm to wildlife from renewable projects to a level that has no harm.
However, households would be WTP £11.98 per annum to change a slight increase in harm to wildlife from renewable pro-
jects to a level that wildlife is improved from the current level
Airpollution
impact
Households are WTP £14.13 to have renewable energy projects that have no increase in air pollution, compared to a pro-
gramme which results in a slight increase in pollution
McFadden pseudo-R2 is also improved with the addition
of the covariates. Louviere et al. (2000) state that a
McFadden statistic in the 0.20–0.30 range is comparable
to an ordinary least square (OLS) adjusted-R2 of 0.70–
0.90. Therefore, the expanded model with covariates is
deemed the superior model, and implicit prices from this
are used in the following discussion. Implicit prices
(“part-worths”) are interpreted as the incremental will-
ingness-to-pay through an increase in electricity charges
per annum per household for a change in any of the at-
tributes. They reveal the following (Table 3).
Looking closer at landscape impacts, moderate and
low landscape impacts were not statistically signicant
compared with a high impact. Respondents thus only
seem WTP to reduce high landscape impacts, but not to
reduce low or moderate impacts. One very interesting
nding is that employment effects are not statistically
signicant determinants of choices or of utility: respon-
dents as a whole did not seem to care about employment
effects to a signicant degree.
An internal validation question was included in the
questionnaire to test for consistency of these results. Re-
spondents were asked to indicate which single attribute
was most important to them. The ordering of the attrib-
utes by votes from respondents was: air pollution, wild-
life, electricity price, landscape and employment. This
shows consistency with the preference results shown in
Table 2. Also, there is inferred consistency of the indirect
utility measurement of individuals as the implicit prices
are in the same rank order. Consistency with preference
theory is also demonstrated by the estimated willing-
ness-to-pay increasing with increased improvement of
the qualitative attributes (for instance, with regard to
wildlife effects).
5.3 Heterogeneous Preferences
One important factor that may determine one’s attitudes
to renewable energy projects is where one lives, in par-
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments
50
ticular whether one lives in the countryside or not. A way
of testing this in our survey is to examine whether there
is a statistical difference between rural and urban esti-
mated MNL coefcients and implicit prices. To do this,
the sample was partitioned according to place of resi-
dence as disclosed in the questionnaire. The sample
population was thus segregated into two groups, those
located in villages or the countryside and those who re-
side in towns and cities. Separate MNL models were then
run for each group (Table 4). A likelihood ratio test re-
jected the null hypothesis that the segregated subsets
were equal at the 5% level. Moderate landscape impacts
now register as signicant in the rural model, as do jobs.
Jobs remain insignicant in the urban sample, but be-
come strongly signicant in the rural model: this is per-
haps unsurprising given most peoples’ likely expecta-
tions about where jobs would be created. Note that the
McFadden pseudo-R2 for the rural subset has increased
to 0.34 from the 0.29 level with the complete sample.
Another reason why attitudes towards renewable en-
ergy investments might vary across people is their in-
come: either because environmental concern is a “lux-
ury” (Hokby and Soderqvist, 2003), or because rising
energy prices hit poorer households disproportionately
hard. To test this hypothesis, the sample was split by
annual household income level into two subsamples: low
income (£16,000 or less per year) and higher income
(greater than £16,000 per year). The log-likelihood ratio
test failed to reject the null hypothesis that the two sub-
sets were equivalent to the complete sample set: there are
no signicant differences in preferences therefore be-
tween these two income groups.
6. Welfare Analysis for Alternative
Investment Plans
One of the strengths of CEs is that estimated coefcients
of the attributes maybe used to estimate the economic
value of different ways in which the attributes can be
combined. In the context of this paper, alternative re-
newable energy investments may be compared in terms
of the welfare changes that they are associated with. To
determine the change in economic surplus from possible
alternative projects in a multi-attribute MNL model, a
“utility difference” is calculated as
12
(1 /)(),
monetary ii
enonomics surplusVV
 (6)
where
V
i is the conditional indirect utility associated
w
it
h
alternative i. The superscript 1 is the base
c
ase-here
dened
as an expansion of an existing fossil fuel
po
w
er
plant-and
superscript 2 is the alternative
r
ene
w
ab
le
energy
case (Bennett and Blamey, 2001). Four
different
energy
project scenarios were
con
s
ide
r
ed:
Large off-shore windmill farm: a 200 MW, 100 tur-
bines each at 80 m nacelle hub height, 6–10 km
from shore.
Large on-shore windmill farm: 160 MW, 80 turbines
each at 80 m nacelle hub height.
Moderate windmill farm: 50 MW, 30 turbines each at
60 m nacelle hub height.
Biomass power plant: 25 MW, emissions stack height
up to 40 m, portions of building up to 30 m, fuelled by
energy crops.
Table 5 gives results for the welfare change of each in-
vestment scenario relative to the case, using Equation (6).
The above values can be interpreted as the price that
households are willing-to-pay (or would have to be of-
fered in compensation in case B) on an annual basis to
have renewable energy projects with the indicated attrib-
ute levels, rather than the base case expansion of fossil
fuel power. These Scottish households place the greatest
value on off-shore wind farms, with the major determi-
nant of the prospective welfare change being the absence
of landscape impacts. This result matches with prior pub-
lic opinion research in Scotland (Scottish Executive,
2003). The next most valued type of energy project is
biomass generation. The major determinant for this type
of project being highly valued is the amount of employ-
ment that is associated with plant operation and agricul-
tural production of the energy crops; and with the wild-
life benets associated with this expansion in biomass
production. Most signicant of the results presented in
Table 5 are the large and substantial negative value
placed on large on-shore wind farms by our sample
households in Scotland. The high level of landscape in-
trusion and the low amount of other benecial attributes
make the promotion and construction of large-scale
windmill farms a poor social welfare choice, other things
being equal. The negative monetary value indicates that
households would have to be compensated in excess of
£19 per year for the construction of this type of project, if
their utility is to be held constant.
It is important, however, to note several caveats. These
alternative projects do not produce the same amount of
electric power. As an example, two moderately sized
wind farms would have to be constructed to generate
similar quantities of electricity each year as a biomass
generating plant. Quantifying the cumulative effect of
numerous projects being constructed in a region is, how-
ever, beyond the scope of this paper.
7. Conclusions
Renewable energy offers a partial solution to the problem
of reducing greenhouse gas emissions whilst meeting
future energy needs. Yet different renewable energy pro-
jects can have varying external costs in terms of impacts
on the landscape, wildlife and air pollution. In addition,
strategies vary in their likely impacts on jobs and elec-
tricity prices. The choice experiment method used in this
paper enables these effects to be jointly evaluated in wel-
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments51
Table 4. Implicit prices of
attributes
comparing rural, urban and all
responden
ts
Model: attributes only (standard error and 95% condence intervals)
Full sample set Rural subset Urban subset
Descriptor Implicit price (£) Implicit price (£) Implicit price (£)
Moderate
Landscape 4.07(2.99) 12.15**(6.3) 0.50(3.31)
(–1.79–9.93) (–0.196–24.5) (–5.99–6.98)
Low
Landscape 3.21 (3.56) –5.68 (7.09) 7.15 (4.03)
(–3.77–10.19) (–19.58–8.20) (–0.74–15.04)
None
Landscape 7.88* (1.94) 5.32 (3.32) 8.73* (2.41)
(4.08–11.68) (–1.18 to –11.83) (4.01–13.45)
None
Wildlife 5.51* (2.18) 6.18 (3.71) 4.43 (2.69)
(1.24–9.78) (–1.08–13.45) (–0.83–9.70)
Improved
Wildlife 10.11* (1.88) 15.23* (3.16) 7.62* (2.42)
(6.43–13.79) (9.04–21.49) (2.87–12.36)
None
Air pollution 14.40* (1.88) 19.08* (3.73) 11.77* (2.08)
(10.72–18.08) (11.77–26.39) (7.70–15.85)
Employment
0.23 (0.22) 1.08* (0.44) –0.19 (0.26)
Log-likelihood (–0.20–0.66) (0.20–1.95) (–0.69–0.32)
–509 –200 –290
No. of observations 836 349 475
Pseudo-R2 0.29 0.34 0.27
*Signicant at 1% level and **signicant at 5% level. Bold indicates monetary implicit values.
Table 5. Welfare change for alternative energy projects
Scenario
Base case
Fossil fuel power station
expansion
A
Large off-shore wind
farm
B
Large on-shore wind
farm
C
Small on-shore wind
farm
D
Biomass power plant
Attribute levels
Landscape Low None High Moderate Moderate
Wildlife None None None None Improve
Air pollution Increase None None None Increase
Employment +2 +5 +4 +1 +70
Welfare change
(£/hsld/yr) +£6.60 –£19.40 +£2.40 +£4.60
fare-consistent terms. This enables conclusions to be
drawn about the net social benets of different renew-
ables investment strategies.
Reviewing our main results, we found a substantial
sensitivity to the creation of projects that will have a high
impact on landscapes. Conversely, there seems to be no
sensitivity, or at least no positive mean willingness-to-
pay, to reduce landscape impacts if the projects are de-
signed to have moderate or low levels of landscape ef-
fects. Wildlife is highly valued by our sample group and
avoiding impacts on wildlife comes out as being as im-
portant as avoiding impacts on landscape. The implicit
price to maintain a neutral impact on wildlife is 75% of
the price households would pay to reduce landscape im-
pacts from high to none. Any project that creates the po-
tential to harm wildlife thus needs to have large offset-
ting benets. The converse of this is the growing of cop-
piced willow as biomass for use in energy production is
expected to create greater bio-diversity on farmland. Our
results show that such increases in wildlife attract a high
economic value. We have not included benets related to
the carbon sequestration function of biomass growth, but
this might be an important part of the overall case for
promoting biomass generation. Conversely, avoiding air
pollution from renewable energy investments was highly
valued by our respondents. This would add to the case
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments
52
against burning biomass for power.
Investing in renewable energy might well result, at
least over the short to medium term, in an increase in
electricity prices. Our results show that, unsurprisingly,
increases in prices reduce consumer utility, since the
coefcient on price in all of our models is negative and
signicant. However, we do not nd in the survey sample
that income groups differ in their preferences towards
renewable energy. However, this study did not have a
sufciently large sample to test for those households near
the ‘energy poverty’ level. This is an issue for further
research.
Turning to spatial issues, there are important differ-
ences between urban and rural responses in this choice
experiment. There is some evidence that accepting nega-
tive environmental impacts from the development of
projects (e.g. landscape impacts) is more acceptable to
the rural population: the rural sample show no willing-
ness-to-pay for reducing landscape impacts from high to
none. Conversely, rural people value wildlife benets
and reductions in air pollution more highly than their
urban cousins (this latter may be due to a perception that
biomass combustion was more likely in rural areas, i.e.,
close to the supply of such material). Finally, we found
that employment creation is a statistically and economi-
cally signicant attribute to the rural sample, but not to
the urban sample. Rural respondents would be will-
ing-to-pay an additional £1.08 per year from each hous-
ehold for each additional full time job created by the re-
newable projects.
8. Acknowledgements
We thank the Scottish Economic Policy Network for
funding the research on which this paper is based, and an
anonymous referee for many useful comments.
REFERENCES
[1] Alvarez Farizo, B., Hanley, N., 2002. Using conjoint
analysis to quantify public preferences over the environ-
mental impacts of wind farms. Energy Policy 30 (2),
107–116.
[2] Bateman, I.J., Carson, R.T., Day, B., Hanemann, M.,
Hanley, N., Hett, I., Jones-Lee, M., Loomes, G., Mourato,
S., Ozdemiroglu, E., Pearce, D., Sugden, R., Swanson, J.,
2002. Economic Valuation with Stated Preference Tech-
niques: A Manual. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
[3] Ben-Akiva, M.E., Lerman, S., 1985. Discrete Choice
Analysis: Theory and Application Travel Demand. MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA.
[4] Bennett, J., Blamey, R. (Eds.). 2001. The Choice Model-
ling Approach to Environmental Valuation. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham, UK.
[5] British Wind Energy Association (BWEA), 2003. Avail-
able from/http://www.bwea.com/index.htmlS (Accessed 1
December 2003).
[6] de Vries, H.J., Roos, C.J., Beurskens, L.W.M., Kooi-
jman-van Dijk, A.L., Uyterlinde, M.A., 2003. Renewable
Electricity Policies in Europe: Country Fact Sheets 2003.
Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands, Amsterdam,
The Netherlands.
[7] Dewar, M., 2003. Report for the University of Glasgow
Renewable Energy Project: Synopsis of Focus Group
Responses. Focus Ecosse, New Lanark.
[8] DTI, 2003. Energy White Paper ‘‘Our Energy Future-
Creating a Low Carbon Economy’’. HMSO, London.
[9] Ek, K., 2002. Valuing the environmental impacts of wind
power: a choice experiment approach. Licentiate Thesis,
Lulea University of Technology, Sweden, p. 40. http://
epubl.luth.se/1402-1757/2002/40/index-en.html (Accessd
1 December 2003).
[10] European Marine Energy Centre (EMEC), 2004. http://
www.emec. org.uk/ (Accessed 1 August 2004).
[11] Hanley, N., MacMillan, D., Wright, R., Bullock, C.,
Simpson, I., Parrisson, D., Crabtree, B., 1998. Contingent
valuation versus choice experiments, estimating the
benets of environmentally sensitive areas of Scotland.
Journal of Agricultural Economics 49(1), 1–15.
[12] Hanley, N., Nevin, C., 1999. Appraising renewable en-
ergy developments in remote communities: the case of the
North Assynt Estate, Scotland. Energy Policy 27,
527–547.
[13] Hanley, N., Mourato, S., Wright, R., 2001. Choice mod-
elling approaches: a superior alternative for environ-
mental valuation? Journal of Economic Surveys 15 (3),
435–462.
[14] Hanley, N., Bergmann, A., Wright, R., 2004. Valuing the
Environmental and Employment Impacts of Renewable
Energy Investment in Scotland. Scotecon, Stirling.
[15] Hassan, Gerald and Partners, Ltd., 2001. Scotland’s Renew-
ables Resources 2001, Vols. 1 and 2. Research commis-
sioned by Scottish Executive. Document No. 2850/G R/03.
[16] Hokby, S., Soderqvist, T., 2003. Elasticities of demand
and willingness to pay for environmental services in
Sweden. Environmental and Resource Economics 26 (3),
361–383.
[17] Lancaster, K., 1966. Anew approach to consumer theory.
Journal of Political Economy 74, 132–157.
[18] Louviere, J.J., Hensher, D., Swait, J., 2000. Stated Choice
Methods: Analysis and Application. University Press,
Cambridge.
[19] Manski, C., 1977. The Structure of Random Utility Mod-
els. Theory and Decision 8, 229–254.
[20] McFadden, D., 1974. Conditional logit analysis of quali-
tative choice behaviour. In: Zarembka, P. (Ed.), Frontiers
in Econometrics. Academic Press, New York.
[21] Nuclear Industry Association (NIA), 2003. Available
from /http:// www.niauk.org/article_33.shtmlS (Accessed
1 December 2003).
[22] OXERA, 2002. A Report to the DTI and the DTLR: Re-
gional Renewable Energy Assessments. Oxera Environ-
Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investments 53
mental, Oxford, UK.
[23] Rose, S.K., et al., 2002. The private provision of public
goods: test of a provision point mechanism for funding
green power programs. Resource and Energy Economics
24, 131–155.
[24] Scottish Executive, 2001. Press Release SE 1472/2001,
http://www.scotland.gov.uk/news/2001/06/se1472.asp
(Accessed 1 August 2004).
[25] Scottish Executive, 2002a. Key Scottish Environmental
Statistics, 2002. A Scottish Executive National Statistics
Publication, Edinburgh.
[26] Scottish Executive, 2002b. Securing a Renewable Future:
Scotland’s Renewable Energy. HMSO, Edinburgh.
[27] Scottish Executive, 2003. Public Attitudes to Wind Farms:
A Survey of Local Residents in Scotland. HMSO, Edin-
burgh.
[28] The Renewables Obligation (Scotland) Order (ROS),
2002. Scottish Statutory Instrument 2002, No. 163.
HMSO, Edinburgh.