The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing with either Frictionless or Frictional Security Markets ()
Keywords:The First Fundamental Valuation Theorems; Transaction Costs; Weak Arbitrage-Freeness; Strict Arbitrage-Freeness; Arbitrage-Free Pricing Theory; Locally Convex Topological Space; Separable Banach Space
1. Introduction
Arbitrage-free asset pricing theory is of fundamental importance in neo-classical finance. In this paper, we consider it in a setting of general state spaces, in particular, locally convex topological space for weakly arbitrage-free security markets, and separable Banach space for strictly arbitrage-free security markets. We deal with both frictionless and frictional security markets.
In the study of mathematical economics, arbitrage-free conditions have always been an important first step toward the general equilibrium theorem with incomplete asset markets (Duffie and Shafer [1,2]; Geanakoplos [3]; Geanakoplos and Shafer [4]; Hirsch, Magill and Mas-Colell [5]; Husseini, Lasry and Magill [6]; and Magill and Shafer [7]). Since the 1980s, for finite period economies, no-arbitrage pricing theory has been applied by various authors to prove the existence of general equilibrium for stochastic economies with incomplete financial markets (Duffie [8-10]; Florenzano and Gourdel [11]; Magill and Shafer [7]; Werner [12,13]; and Zhang [14]). In those works, the finite number of possible states of nature and the finite-dimensional commodity space are usually assumed in order for the proofs to be carried out for the general equilibrium model with incomplete financial markets. Our model considers a general state space which may have an infinite number of states.
Many mathematical economists usually apply Stiemke’s Lemma, a strict version of Farkas-Minkowski’s Lemma, to study the asset pricing theory with no-arbitrage conditions, for example, discrete-time models of dynamic asset pricing theory (Duffie [9,10]) and the theory of economic equilibrium with incomplete asset markets (Geanakoplos [3]; Geanakoplos and Shafer [4]; Hirsch, Magill and Mas-Colell [5]; Husseini, Lasry and Magill [6]; and Magill and Shafer [7]) where the commodity space is of finite dimension. Farkas-Minkowski’s Lemma and Stiemke’s Lemma are in essence the mathematical counter part of the asset pricing theory with no-arbitrage conditions. In this paper, we obtain extensions (to the general state space in our discussion) of Farkas-Minkowski’s Lemma and Stiemke’s Lemma by applying Clark’s separating hyperplane theorems (Clark [15,16]), and thus establish our main results.
Harrison and Kreps [17] initiated the study of martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod security markets. They first introduced general theory of arbitrage in a two-period economy with uncertainty, and then extended it to the models of multiperiod security markets and the models of continuous-time securities markets. Kreps [18] studied arbitrage and equilibrium in economies with infinitely many commodities and presented an abstract analysis of “arbitrage” in economies that have infinite dimensional commodity space. Harrison and Pliska [19] studied martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Dalang, Morton and Willinger [20] studied equivalent martingale measures and no-arbitrage in stochastic securities market models. Back and Pliska [21] studied the fundamental theorem of asset pricing with an infinite state space and showed some equivalent relations on arbitrage. Jacod and Sgiryaev [22] studied local martingales and the fundamental asset pricing theorems in the discrete-time case. These papers studied fundamental theorems of asset pricing in multiperiod financial models with the help of techniques from stochastic analysis. Our work is based on separating hyperplane theorems and does not rely on assumptions made for stochastic analysis to be able to carry out in the above models.
Friction in markets has attracted attention of several works in this field recently. Chen [23] examined the incentives and economic roles of financial innovation and at the same time studied the effectiveness of the replication-based arbitrage valuation approach in frictional economies (the friction means holding constraints). Jouini and Kallal [24] derived the implications of the absence of arbitrage in securities markets models where traded securities are subject to short-sales constraints and where the borrowing and lending rates differ, and showed that a securities price system is arbitrage free if and only if there exists a numeraire and an equivalent probability measure for which the normalized (by the numeraire) price processes of traded securities are supermartingales. Jouini and Kallal [25] derived the implications from the absence of arbitrage in dynamic securities markets with bid-ask spreads. The absence of arbitrage is equivalent to the existence of at least an equivalent probability measure that transforms some process between the bid and the ask price processes of traded securities into a martingale. Pham and Touzi [26] addressed the problem of characterization of no arbitrage (strictly arbitrage-free) in the presence of friction in a discrete-time financial model, and extended the fundamental theorem of asset pricing under a non-degeneracy assumption. The friction is described by the transaction cost rates for purchasing and selling the securities. We follow the model for transaction costs from Pham and Touzi [26], and then extend the first fundamental valuation theorems of asset pricing from frictionless security markets to frictional security markets, for general state space. Again, their stochastic analysis method requires stronger assumptions than ours. In addition, their arbitrage-free conditions are slightly different from ours based on that of Duffie [9].
Section 2 presents our model without transaction costs, we define the weakly arbitrage-free security markets and strictly arbitrage-free security markets, following Duffie [9]. In the next two sections, we establish the first fundamental valuation theorem of asset pricing (a necessary and sufficient condition for arbitrage-freeness) with weakly arbitrage-free security markets in Section 3 and strictly arbitrage-free security markets in Section 4. In the rest of the paper we extend our work to markets with transaction costs, following the model of Pham and Touzi [26]. The transaction cost model is presented in Section 5, and the corresponding first fundamental valuation theorems of asset pricing are done in Sections 6 and 7. Section 8 concludes our article with some remarks.
2. Frictionless Security Markets
We consider a two-period model (dates 0 and 1) with uncertainty over the states of nature in the date 1. The unknown nature of the future is represented by a general set
of possible states of nature, one of which will be revealed as true. Here we make no assumption about the probability of these states. The
securities are given by a return “matrix”
, where
denotes the number of units of account paid by security
. Let
denote the vector of prices of
securities. A portfolio
has market value
and payoff
.
Let
be a topological space consisting of processes in
,
is the positive cone of
. Let
be the dual space composed of the continuous linear functionals on
,
the positive cone of the space
(the space of all positive continuous linear functionals on
) and
the interior of the cone
(the space of all strictly positive continuous linear functionals on
):
.
In this paper, we assume
for
. Then
. Our proof must adopt the following notation
and
.
[Definition ]">1] The frictionless market
is weakly arbitrage-free if any portfolio
of securities has a positive market value
whenever it has a positive payoff
.
[Definition ]">2] The frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free if (1) any portfolio
of securities has a strictly positive market value
whenever it has a positive non-zero payoff
; and (2) any portfolio
of securities has a zero market value
whenever it has a zero payoff
.
Definition 2 implies Definition 1 obviously. We follow the definition for arbitrage opportunity as provided by Duffie [9,]">10]. An arbitrage is a portfolio
with either (1)
and
, or (2)
and
. That is to say, the frictionless market
admits an arbitrage opportunity if there exists an portfolio
of securities such that either (1)
and
, or (2)
and
. Consequently, we can define the strictly arbitrage-free (no arbitrage) frictionless market
as follows.
[Definition 2¢] The frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free if (1) any portfolio
of securities has a strictly positive market value
whenever it has a positive non-zero payoff
; and (2) any portfolio
of securities has a positive market value
whenever it has a positive payoff
.
[Lemma ]">1] Definitions 2 and 2’ are equivalent.
An arbitrage is therefore, in effect, a portfolio offering “something for nothing”. Not surprisingly, an arbitrage is naturally ruled out in reality. And this fact gives a characterization of security prices as follows: A valuation functional is a functional
for the weakly arbitrage-free frictionless market
with consistency
; and a functional
for the strictly arbitrage-free frictionless market
with consistency
, where
. The valuation functional is called to be a positive linear consistent valuation operator for the weakly arbitrage-free frictionless market, a strictly positive linear consistent valuation operator for the strictly arbitrage-free frictionless market, respectively.
The idea of arbitrage and the absence of arbitrage opportunities is fundamental in finance. The strict arbitrage-freeness is important in the study of general equilibrium theory with incomplete asset markets (Husseini, Lasry and Magill [6]; Werner [13]; and Magill and Shafer [7]). Theorem 2 to be presented in the following is an important step in the study of equilibrium for economies with general state spaces considered in our work. The principal mathematical tool applied here is the Separating Hyperplane Theorems of Clark [15] and [16].
[Fact ]">1] (Clark [16]) Suppose
and
are non-empty disjoint convex cones in a locally convex topological vector space
. Then there exists a non-zero continuous linear functional
separating
from
:
for all
and
for all
if and only if
. Moreoverif
, then for any
we may select
so that
.
[Fact ]">2] (Clark [15]) Suppose
and
are non-empty convex cones (with vertices at the origin) in a separating Banach space
. Then there exists a non-zero continuous linear functional
strictly separating N from M:
for all
and
for all
if and only if
.
Fact 1 and 2 will be used to prove Theorems 1 and 2 in Sections 3 and 4, Theorems 3 and 4 in Sections 6 and 7, respectively. We assume
, which is a topological space, then
is the positive cone of
, which is a positive closed convex cone of
with its vertex at the origin. The marketed subspace

is a linear subspace of the space
.
3. Weakly Arbitrage-Free Security Valuation Theorem with Frictionless Security Markets
In this section, we assume that
is a locally convex topological space.
[Proposition 1] The frictionless market
is weakly arbitrage-free if and only if
.
Proof.
implies that there exists
such that
and
. On the other hand,
implies that
from Definition 1, then
. Thus
and
, that is,
.
Conversely, if there exists
such that
and
, then
. Thus
and
.
This is a contradiction! Therefore the frictionless market
is weakly arbitrage-free. Q.E.D.
[Theorem 1] The frictionless market
is weakly arbitrage-free if and only if there exists a positive functional
satisfying
.
Proof. Both
and
are closed and convex cones of
with their vertices at the origin.
The frictionless market
is weakly arbitrage-free if and only if
. Note that
is a convex set. Let
, then
is a (non-empty) convex set. Both 
and
are non-empty disjoint convex cones
.
implies
. Clark [16] stated that there exists a non-zero continuous linear functional
separating
from
, that is,
for all
and
for all
. Moreover,
.
is a positive continuous linear functional on
. In fact, for any
and natural number
,
and
. Therefore,
. Thus
.
That is,
is a positive continuous linear functional on
.
Thus
is represented by some
and
by
for any
. In fact,
is represented by some
and
by
for any
. The fact that
implies
. If
, then there exists
such that
. Take
, then
and
. The contradiction means
.
Since
is a linear space,
for all
, that is,
for all
. Then
. And therefore, the vector
is that we want.
The converse is obvious. Q.E.D.
[Remark 1] If
is a finite set, then
is an Euclidean space, Definition 1 is the usual concept of weak arbitrage-freeness. Theorem 1 is the well-known Farkas-Minkowski’s Lemma (Duffie [9]; Farkas [27] and Franklin [28]).
[Remark 2] Theorem 1 (The Extension of Farkas-Minkowski’s Lemma) means that the present value of the securities prices at date 0 is the value of their returns at date 1.
4. Strictly Arbitrage-Free Security Valuation Theorem with Frictionless Security Markets
In this section, we assume that
is a separable Banach space. We prove Proposition 2 and Theorem 2 by using Definition 2 of the strictly arbitrage-free frictionless market
.
[Proposition 2] The frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free if and only if
and
intersect precisely at
, that is,
.
Proof.
implies that there exists
such that
and
. If
, then
from Definition 2 (1),
, a contradiction! If
, then
from Definition 2 (2),
and
. Thus
. And hence,
.
For sufficiency, we must consider two cases: (1) If there exists
such that
and
, then
and
, a contradiction. Therefore, any portfolio
of securities has a positive non-zero market value
whenever it has a positive payoff
. (2)
If there exists
such that
and
, we discuss the problem for the following two settings. (2.1) When
, then
, thus
. This is a contradiction! (2.2)
When
, then
and
, thus
. This is a contradiction! The two contradictions mean that the frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free. Q.E.D.
[Theorem 2] The frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free if and only if there exists a strictly positive functional
satisfying
.
Proof. Both
and
are closed and convex cones of
with their vertices at the origin.
Since
is a polyhedral (convex) cone in
and
is a closed convex cone of
, then
is a closed convex cone from Lemma of Clark [15], that is,
. Thus
is a closed convex cone
.
The frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free if and only if
. We claim that
. On the contrary, we assume that there exists
then
and
for
and
. Thus
contradicting the conclusion
and
.
Note that
. It follows that
. Thus
. Since both
and
are non-empty convex cones with vertices at the origin in the separable Banach space
, Theorem 5 in Clark [15] states that there exists a non-zero continuous linear functional
on
strictly separating
from
, that is,
for all
and
for all
.
The condition
for all
implies that
is a strictly positive continuous linear functional on
. Thus
is represented by some
and
by
for any
.
Since
is a linear space,
for all
, that is,
for all
. It follows that
. The vector
is that we want.
The converse is again obvious. Q.E.D.
[Remark 1] If
is a finite set, then
is an Euclidean space, Definition 1 is the usual concept of strict arbitrage-freeness. Theorem 2 is the well-known Stiemke’s Lemma (Duffie [9,10]).
[Remark 2] Theorem 2 (The Extension of Stiemke’s Lemma) means that the present value of the securities prices at date 0 is the value of their returns at date 1.
[Remark 3] If
where
is a linear functional on
, we can prove Theorem 2 by Kreps [18]. The sufficient condition is obvious, we only need prove the necessary condition. Take
, then any element
is of the form
where
. Take
as a linear functional on
solving the equation
for all
, i.e.
and take
. If the frictionless market
is strictly arbitrage-free, then the pair
admits no free lunches. Kreps’ conditions (4.7) and (4.10) are applied, then the pair
is
-viable from Theorem 3 (Kreps [18]), that is, the pair
has the extension property for
. Thus the necessary condition is obtained.
5. Frictional Security Markets
Suppose that there are transaction costs in the trading, the coefficients
and
are respectively the transaction cost rates for purchasing and selling the security
. Then the algebraic cost induced by (buying) a position
units of security
is
and the algebraic gain induced by (selling) a position
units of security
is
. We introduce the functions
defined by

and the functions
defined by

Then
.
For any integer
, a function
is subliner if, for any
,
,
and
,

The function
is sublinear, and hence convex. Therefore the function
is also sublinear, and hence convex.
The total cost or gain induced by (trading) a portfolio
is
. We define the function
by

Then the total cost or gain induced by (trading) a portfolio
is
. As we know, the function
is sublinear, and hence convex.
[Definition ]">3] The frictional market
is weakly arbitrage-free if any portfolio
of securities has a positive total cost or gain
whenever it has a positive payoff
.
We note that Definitions 2 and 2’ are equivalent. However, in the presence of transaction costs, the corresponding Definitions 4 and 4’ (as follows) are not. We establish Theorem 4 for Definition 4’ of the strictly arbitrage-free frictional market
.
[Definition ]">4] The frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free if (1) any portfolio
of securities has a strictly positive total cost or gain
whenever it has a positive non-zero payoff
; and (2) any portfolio
of securities has a zero total cost or gain
whenever it has a zero payoff
.
[Definition 4’] The frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free if (1) any portfolio
of securities has a strictly positive total cost or gain
whenever it has a positive non-zero payoff
; and (2) any portfolio
of securities has a positive total cost or gain
whenever it has a positive payoff
.
Definition 4 obviously implies Definition 4’. Definition 4’ does not imply Definition 4 because of the presence of friction. In the frictionless model, we define the marketed subspace

of the space
to prove the first fundamental theorems of asset pricing. In the frictional model, we can’t consider the corresponding marketed “subspace”
. In fact, this marketed “subspace”
isn’t a subspace of the space
. Instead, we define the subset
in the space
as follows

[Lemma 2]
is a closed and convex cone in the space
.
Proof.
is a closed cone obviously since the function
is continuous and sublinear.
For any
and
, there exist
and
such that
,
and
,
. Thus
since the function
is sublinear, and
. Therefore
. Since
is a cone,
is convex. Q.E.D.
For simplicity, we use the following notations in the subsequent sections.

We define the box product of two vectors
and
by

6. Weakly Arbitrage-Free Security Valuation Theorem with Frictional Security Markets
In this section, we assume that
is a locally convex topological space.
[Proposition ]">3] The frictional market
is weakly arbitrage-free if and only if
.
Proof.
implies that there exists
such that
and
. On the other hand,
implies that
from Definition 3. Then
and
, that is,
.
Conversely, if there exists
such that
and
, then
. Thus
and
.
This is a contradiction! Therefore, any portfolio
of securities has a positive total cost or gain
whenever it has a positive payoff
. Q.E.D.
[Remark] The proof of Proposition 3 only requires the property that
is a closed and convex cone in the space
and doesn’t need the explicit definition of the function
, so does Proposition 3.
[Theorem ]">3] The frictional market
is weakly arbitrage-free if and only if there exists a positive functional
satisfying

Proof. Both
and
are closed and convex cones of
with their vertices at the origin.
The frictional market
is weakly arbitrage-free if and only if
. Note that
is a convex set. Let
, then
is a (non-empty) convex set. Both 
and
are non-empty disjoint convex cones,
.
implies
. Clark [16] stated that there exists a non-zero continuous linear functional
separating
from
, that is,
for all
and
for all
. Moreover,
.
From the proof of Theorem 1,
is a positive continuous linear functional on
, and
is represented by some
and
by
for any
.
On the other hand, the fact that
for all
implies
for all 
and
for
. Then
for all
. And hence we have

for all
. For each
, assigning
, we have

that is,
. Thus

For each
, we assign
instead, it follows that

that is,
. Thus

Therefore, for any
,

The vector
is thus what we want:

Conversely, assume that there exists a positive functional
satisfying

For any
,

For any
,

And for any
,

Thus

Summarying over
, we then have, for any
,

Therefore the frictional market
is weakly arbitrage-free. Q.E.D.
[Remark] Theorem 3 means the first fundamental theorem of weakly arbitrage-freeness with frictional security markets. If there exists no transaction costs, that is,
and
, then Theorem 3 reduces to Theorem 1.
7. Strictly Arbitrage-Free Security Valuation Theorem with Frictional Security Markets
In this section, we assume that
is a separable Banach space. We prove the following Proposition 4 and Theorem 4 for Definition 4’ of the strictly arbitrage-free frictional market
.
[Proposition ]">4] The frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free if and only if
and
intersect precisely at
, that is,
.
Proof.
implies that there exists
such that
and
. If
, then
from Definition 4’(1),
, which is a contradiction! If
, then
from Definition 4’(2),
and
. Thus
and hence
.
For sufficiency, we must consider two cases: (1) If there exists
such that
and
then
. Take
such that
and
, then
which is a contradiction. It follows that any portfolio
of securities has a strictly positive total cost or gain
whenever it has a positive payoff
. (2) If there exists
such that
and
, then
. Take
such that
and
, then
, which is a contradiction! The two contradictions mean that the frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free. Q.E.D.
[Remark] The proof of Proposition 4 doesn’t use the representation of the function
, then Proposition 4 holds for usual total cost or gain function.
[Theorem ]">4] The The frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free if and only if there exists a strictly positive functional
satisfying

Proof. Both
and
are closed and convex cones of
with the vertices at the origin.
Since
is a polyhedral (convex) cone in
and
is a closed convex cone of
,
is a closed convex cone from Lemma of Clark [15], that is,
. Thus
is a closed convex cone
.
The frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free if and only if
. We claim that
.
On the contrary, we assume that there exists
. Then 
and
for
and
. Thus
contradicting the fact that
(which follows from
in Proposition 4).
Note that
, then
.
Thus,
. Since both
and
are non-empty convex cones with vertices at the origin in the separable Banach space
, Theorem 5 in Clark [15] states that there exists a non-zero continuous linear functional
on
strictly separating
from
. That is,
for all
and
for all
.
The condition
for all
implies that
is a strictly positive continuous linear functional on
. Thus
is represented by some
and
by
for any
.
The next proof is the same as the corresponding part in Theorem 3. Q.E.D.
[Remark] Theorem 4 means the first fundamental theorem of strict arbitrage-freeness with frictional security markets. If there exists no transaction costs, that is,
and
, then Theorem 4 reduces to Theorem 2.
8. Concluding Remarks
In Section 4, we examine the following problem: whether the security prices
can be represented by strictly positive continuous linear functional
as
. More precisely, for the security prices
and the returns
, we study the existence of strictly positive continuous linear functional
as
. Ross [29] and Kreps [18] studied how to extend a linear functional
on
to
that is strictly positive continuous. However, the existence of the linear functional
on
with
is not at all an assured condition. It holds under certain conditions. For example, if
, our result is an analogue of theirs. In the equation
, each linear functional
on
corresponds to a vector
and each vector
corresponds to a linear functional
on
only if
is column linear independent. Therefore, our results in Section 4 are the same as theirs under the assumption “
is column linear independent”. But in general, this may not hold.
Dalang, Morton and Willinger [20] and Jacod and Sgiryaev [22] studied arbitrage-free model, weakly arbitrage-free model, and strongly arbitrage-free model, provided simple proofs of the two fundamental theorems of asset pricing theory. Jacod and Sgiryaev [22] proved that the three concepts are equivalent to each another. In fact, the three concepts are strictly arbitrage-free securities’ price-return pair in Section 2 of our paper. Jacod and Sgiryaev [22] assumed that
is an integrable (finite expectation) random variable (martingale condition). But we only assume
is in the locally convex topological space
for weakly arbitragefree frictionless market (Section 3), and
is in the separable Banach space for strictly arbitrage-free frictionless market (Section 4). Therefore our study in Sections 2, 3 and 4 is more general than Jacod and Sgiryaev [22].
Pham and Touzi [26] studied frictional markets with the transaction cost rates for purchasing and selling the securities, addressed the problem of characterization of no arbitrage opportunity (strict arbitrage-freeness) in the presence of transaction costs in a discrete-time financial model, and extended the fundamental theorem of asset pricing under a non-degeneracy assumption. We also study the first fundamental valuation theorems of asset pricing from frictionless security markets to frictional security markets in Sections 5, 6 and 7. However, our results are different from those in Pham and Touzi [26] in the following two aspects. (1) The definition of no arbitrage opportunity in Pham and Touzi [26] is different from our definition of strict arbitrage-freeness. (2) Our proofs of Theorems 3 and 4 are different from Pham and Touzi [26]. In fact, we provide the proof by using theory of functional analysis, while Pham and Touzi [26] applied stochastic analysis to prove their results. Therefore, our result works for more general space than theirs.
Frictional economies are fundamentally different from their frictionless counterparts. The theory of general economic equilibrium for frictional economies with incomplete financial markets should be studied. We make the first step by establishing the corresponding no-arbitrage (that is, strictly arbitrage-free) pricing theory. From the first fundamental valuation theorems of asset pricing in general state space with transaction costs we have obtained here, one may further study the corresponding existence of general equilibrium for frictional economy with infinite-dimensional commodity space and incomplete financial markets.
In Section 7, we proved the equivalent conditions (Proposition 4 and Theorem 4) of strictly arbitrage-free frictional market by using Definition 4’. There are some difference between Definitions 4 and 4’. In fact, we can obtain the following (weaker) results for strictly arbitrage-free frictional market as defined by Definition 4.
[Proposition] If the frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free, then
and
intersect precisely at
, that is,
.
[Theorem] If the The frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free, then there exists a strictly positive functional
satisfying

The proofs of Proposition and Theorem are from the proofs of Proposition 4 and Theorem 4. Conversely, we can’t check the sufficiency. The proof of Theorem 4 holds, too. If

where
is a strictly positive vector, then, for any
,

then

that is,

If any portfolio
of securities has a zero payoff
, then it has a positive total cost or gain
for the portfolio
, and a positive total cost or gain
for the portfolio
, thus

For any portfolio
of securities, we can’t obtain a zero total cost or gain
when it has a zero payoff
. That is to say, we can’t make sure that Definition 4 (2) holds. We can’t come to the conclusion that the frictional market
is strictly arbitrage-free in the sense of Definition 4.
Funding
This work is supported by Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (SSHRC Insight Development Grant Number: 430-2012-0698), National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC Grant Numbers: 70825003 and 71273271) Major Basic Research Plan of Renmin University of China (Grant Number: 14XNL001)
NOTES
*Corresponding author.