1. Introduction
In continuous time settings, the option beta of [1] based on the [2] pricing model properly reflects the risks inherent in options. However, since empirical studies focus on discrete return intervals, the utilization of continuous-time betas may give rise to a distortion of an unknown magnitude. For example, [3] examine the expected option returns under very general assumptions. For building zero-beta index straddles, [3] employ the instantaneous version of beta and present empirical evidence that option returns appear to be other than theoretically expected. One possible explanation for these findings might be the incorrect application of a non-discretized risk measure1.
Based on Black-Scholes option prices, [6] present closed-form expressions for discrete-time option betas. In particular, they distinguish between an asset beta, which is important for asset pricing, and a covariance beta, relevant mostly for hedging purposes. Furthermore, they show that, unlike the instantaneous beta of [1] derived from the continuous-time arbitrage-free perspective, the discrete-time betas depend explicitly on the expected rate of return on the underlying asset. The differences between discrete-time and continuous-time option betas are also likely to be of a significant magnitude. However, in the limit, when the individual planning horizon becomes very short, all types of betas coincide.
This paper extends the option betas presented by [1,6]. The starting point is the CAPM option pricing model of [7], where the length of the individual planning horizon is a determinant of an option’s value. In particular, we show how the beta of the underlying asset affects both an options’s covariance beta and its asset pricing beta. However, in contrast to [6], the generalized option betas are shown to coincide if the options are evaluated according to the CAPM option pricing model. We present all option betas in terms of Black-Scholes option prices. Therfore, they are easy to use in practice.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the assumptions and notation used. Section 3 summarizes the theoretical results about CAPM option pricing in discrete time. In Section 4, we present closed form solutions for option betas and compare them to the option betas of [1,6]. Section 5 concludes.
2. Assumptions and Notation
The assumptions and notation used in this study are exactly the same as those in [7]. In brief, we use the default assumptions of the CAPM, and additionally assume that the instantaneous rate of return on any asset and the market portfolio have a joint normal distribution.
We use the following notation throughout this paper:
Investor’s planning horizon
Time-to-maturity of an option
Exercise price of an option
Price of an underlying asset S
Price of a call on an asset S
Cash flow of the underlying asset
Cash flow of the call
Instantaneous risk-free rate of interest
Instantaneous rate of return on asset S
Instantaneous rate of return on the market index
Standardized cash flow of the market portfolio (
)
Expected instantaneous rate of return on asset S
Expected instantaneous rate of return on the market index
Instantaneous volatility of the rate of return on asset S
Instantaneous volatility of the rate of return on the market index
Coefficient of correlation between rs and rm
Market price per unit risk for the investor’s planning horizon Furthermore, we consider a call option on a non-dividend asset S expiring at time
when the investor’s planning horizon extends to time
. The investor’s planning horizon may be equal to or shorter than the time-to-maturity of the option. We denote the remaining time-to-maturity of the option as
and the length of the planning horizon as
. For the difference between the investor’s planning horizon and the time-to-maturity of the call, we write
. Our aim is to determine the discrete-time beta of an option at time 0.
As usual in option pricing theory, we assume that options, underlyings, and risk-free assets are traded in the market during an option’s remaining time-to-maturity. However, we assume that investors in general do not aim to replicate an options payoff by continuously trading the underlying and a risk-free asset. Reasons for this might be transactions costs, bid-ask spreads, or insufficient market liquidity; moreover, if equity is characterized as an option on the company’s assets the underlying does not trade at all. Therefore, we assume that options are not traded at Black-Scholes prices but at discrete-time CAPM option prices according to [7] which include Black-Scholes prices as a limiting case. Due to this assumption our analysis of discrete-time option betas is more general than the one of [6].
To clearly arrange our analytical results, we use the following notation for the Black-Scholes price of a call with time-to-maturity
when the price of the current asset
is replaced by
and the strike price
is replaced by
:
(1)
where

In the following, we use some auxiliary variables. Equation (1) will be evaluated for
and four different values of
,

Accordingly,
,
,
and
are used to describe the resulting values of (1). Notice that Equation (1) is linear in
and
, that is,

3. The Lognormal CAPM in Discrete Time
3.1. Security Market Line in a Lognormal Market
The security market line of the CAPM in discrete time is
(2)
With the given parameters, for a bivariate normal distribution of rates of return on the market
, and the underlying asset
, both with respect to the holding period
, two definitions of
are possible. We refer to
(3)
as the asset’s pricing beta, and
(4)
as the asset’s covariance beta2. Note that we define the parameter
as the rate of return of the expected value, whereas
is also used in the literature to identify the expected rate of return. If the latter definition is preferred,
must be replaced with
throughout this paper. Of course, since both the asset pricing beta and the covariance beta depend on the expected return of an asset we cannot use (2) to explain returns in a lognormal market. However, setting (3) and (4) equal leads to the lognormal security market line in discrete time. After several conversions, we obtain
(5)
Of course, if (5) holds in the market, an asset’s pricing beta (3) and its covariance beta (4) coincide, and they are equal to one if
. In the limit
, when the investor’s planning horizon becomes very short, we can apply L’Hôspital’s rule to (3) and (4) to show that
(6)
Therefore, in continuous-time
, the security market line (5) is
(7)
the well-known intertemporal CAPM of [8]. However, [9], addressing the relevance of the discrete-time analysis, remarks that “the continuous-time solution is a valid approximation to the discrete-time solution, and its accuracy is a function of the actual structure of returns and the length of the ‘true’ discrete-time interval. I thought to argue for the superiority of discrete-time analysis over the continuous analysis because discrete-time includes continuous time as a limiting case”.
3.2. CAPM Option Pricing in a Lognormal Market
[7] extend the option pricing equations of [2,10], and [11]. In particular, they show that, besides the option’s time-to-maturity, the individual planning horizon is a determinant of an option’s value in discrete time as well. The generalized pricing equations can be presented in terms of the Black-Scholes option values.
For a call option, the certainty equivalent valuation equation of the CAPM is

where
(8)
Here,
describes the market price per unit risk for the investor’s planning horizon. In the following, it is assumed that the investor’s planning horizon is shorter than or equal to the time-to-maturity of the option
. Then, in a lognormal market, the expected cash flow of a call and the covariance between the cash flows of the call and the standardized return of the market portfolio are3
(9)
(10)
Inserting (9) and (10) into (8) yields the CAPM option pricing model of [7]4,
(11)
In risk-neutral settings,

and Equation (11) equals the call option price of [2].
4. Discrete Option Betas
4.1. An Option’s Pricing Beta
The definition of an option’s asset pricing beta with respect to the holding period is
(12)
Using
and (9) results in
(13)
Furthermore, with recourse to (3), (13) yields
(14)
[1,6] derive option betas where the options are evaluated at the Black-Scholes option price (1) and not at the more general CAPM valuation Equation (8), which includes [2] as a special case. Accordingly, to achieve their results, the current call price has to be replaced in (14),
Furthermore, the option prices at the end of the holding period also have to be replaced. Thus, we split the option’s time-to-maturity as follows.
(15)
For the remaining period

must apply if the option is evaluated (risk neutral) at the Black-Scholes option price at the end of the holding period. Therefore,
, and (14) results in
(16)
Since
is linear in
and
, and

as

applies to the remaining period
, (16) yields
(17)
Now, let’s consider two special cases of (17). If the planning horizon becomes very short
, we can apply L’Hôspital’s rule and (6) to achieve
(18)
where, if the lognormal security market line (7) holds,
(19)
and
is equal to the option’s delta.
Therefore, in continuous time, the beta of an option with respect to the market is given by the beta of its underlying asset times the elasticity of the option price with respect to the stock price. This is a well known result of [1]5.
In discrete time
, if
and the distributions of the rates of return on the market
and the underlying asset
are bivariate normal, then
and
. In this case,
and (17) is equal to Equation (2.15) of [6],
(20)
who analyze the beta of an option in discrete time with respect to the underlying6. However, if
, the bivariate normal distribution of the rates of return on the market
and the underlying asset
affects both the beta of an option with respect to the underlying and the beta of the underlying, even if options are equal to Black-Scholes prices at the end of the holding period.
4.2. An Option’s Covariance Beta
The definition of the discrete covariance beta is
(21)
where, in a lognormal market,
(22)
Using (10) and (22), (21) is equal to
(23)
Using (4), we can transform (23) to

Using similar arguments as above (L’Hôspital’s rule and (6)), we obtain the special cases, [1]

and [6], Equation (2.10),

4.3. Equality of an Option’s Asset Pricing and Covariance Beta
An option’s asset pricing beta can easily be converted to its covariance beta. Inserting (11) into (13) results in7

Using the definition of
in (8) and the definition
yields

which is equal to the covariance beta (23). Hence, in contrast to [6], an options’s asset pricing beta and its covariance beta coincide if options are evaluated according to the CAPM option pricing model of [7].
5. Conclusions
Adequate risk measures are essential for both hedging and performance evaluation. This paper extends the option betas presented by [1,6]. Whereas [1] present continuous-time option betas, [6] analyze discrete-time option betas with respect to the stock price and the Black-Scholes option prices. They distinguish between the concepts of a covariance beta, which is based on the covariance between stock and option price changes, and an asset pricing beta, which is related to the option’s expected returns.
We utilize a more general, lognormal option pricing equation, which explicitly incorporates the planning horizon and the investors’ expectations about the development of the underlying asset and the market portfolio, and show how the beta of the underlying asset affects both an options’s covariance beta and its asset pricing beta. Furthermore, the two risk measures coincide if the options are evaluated according to the CAPM option pricing model of [7]. The derived option betas are likely to exhibit a notable economic value. Their utilization might reduce the shortcomings of continuous-time betas applied in empirical studies where the application of discrete-time return measures appears to be more appropriate. Moreover, the option betas are clearly arranged in terms of Black-Scholes option prices and easy to use in practice.
Appendix A
Definite Normal Integrals
[12] has collected a list of normal integrals, including8
(A1)
where
.
To prove the results obtained by [13] and establish the covariance of the cash flow of a CAPM call with the return on the market portfolio, a minor extension of (A1) is required,
(A2)
Proof. Let’s start with the left-hand side. The exponent in (A2) extends to

Using

solves

which also equals the first derivative of the right-hand side of (A2),

Appendix B
Computation of the CAPM Call Option Price
Computation of 
10See [7] with minor conversions. |
When the planning horizon is shorter that the time-to-maturity, we use the results presented by [13] who obtained the expected value of the call for
in terms of a Black--Scholes value of an European-style call as9

Furthermore, we take into account that the call option price in a lognormal market for the case
can be shown to equal10

where

Thus, we can express the expected value of a call at the end of the holding period as
(B1)
where
(B2)
and
(B3)
are Black-Scholes prices of options with time to maturity of
. Splitting (B1) in three integrals and utilizing the solution presented by [13] gives

where

and

Computation of
.
We compute the covariance between the value of the call and the return on the market portfolio at the end of the holding period using the decomposition theorem. First, to compute
, we must integrate

with
and
defined as in (B2) and (B3), respectively. Using the definition of the conditional density
we obtain the following:
(B4)
Note that the conditional density of the bivariate normal distribution equals the density of the normal distribution with the parameters

such that

(B4) is therefore equal to
(B5)
For the sake of clarity, we first consider only one term of (B5),
(B6)
and split it into two separate components,
(B7)
and
(B8)
We start with (B8). Its exponent

can be transformed into

Next, we make following substitution

Using
, (B8) is equal to
(B9)
where

Thus, the integral term of (B9) has the same structure as the left-hand side of (A2). Applying

into (B8) yields
(B10)
Similarly, the exponent of (B7)

can be transformed into

Substituting

and using
in (B7) leads to

where

Again, using (A2) yields

such that (B7) takes the following form:
(B11)
Using (B10) and (B11) in (B6) and multiplying by
from (B5) gives

The remaining terms in (B5) can be computed in an analogue way such that
takes the simple form

where

The covariance
is thus given by

NOTES
2To calculate the moments of the lognormal distribution, see, e.g., Appendix A in [11].
3The deviation is based on a minor extension of a known integral of the normal distribution, see Appendix A.
4A proof of this slightly modified valuation equation is given in Appendix B. A valuation equation for puts and the generalized put betas which follow can be derived in an analogue way. Therefore, the study focuses on call options only.
5See [1] p. 190 and p. 210.
6Notice that we use the symbol
for the holding whereas [6] use
. In addition, [6] define the parameter
as the rate of return of the expected value, whereas we use it to identify the expected rate of return. To make our results comparable with theirs, the parameter
must be replaced with
in [6].
7Since
, we have the term
twice in the numerator, with opposite signs and hence cancel them out.
8See [12], p. 403, integral 10,010.8.
9See Appendix A.