Arbitrage in General Equilibrium

Abstract

Normal trade in goods assumes two sectors that co-exist for reasons such as comparative advantage and interact via trade. Arbitrage trade in goods assumes two markets that artificially exist and converge via trade. Restoration of the law of one price via arbitrage creates one sector out of two, and in general equilibrium, equalizes opportunity cost of resources used in production. Arbitrage does not occur in a vacuum, such that when the high (low) price of a good decreases (increases) in its artificially segmented market during arbitrage, the supply of the good falls (rises), the resources used intensively in that good earn lower (higher) returns, affecting security prices, and the supply of those resources in that good’s production fall (rise).

Share and Cite:

O. Varela, "Arbitrage in General Equilibrium," Modern Economy, Vol. 3 No. 4, 2012, pp. 396-401. doi: 10.4236/me.2012.34051.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] J. M. Harrison and D. M. Kreps, “Martingales and Arbitrage in Multiperiod Securities Markets,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 20, No. 3, 1979, pp. 381-408. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(79)90043-7
[2] J. Werner, “Arbitrage and the Existence of Competitive Equilibrium,” Econometrica, Vol. 55, No. 6, 1987, pp. 1403-1418. doi:10.2307/1913563
[3] R. A. Dana, C. Le Van and F. Magnien, “On the Different Notions of Arbitrage and Existence of Equilibrium,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 87, No. 1, 1999, pp. 169-193. doi:10.1006/jeth.1999.2518
[4] F. H. Page Jr., M. H. Wooders and P. K. Monteiro, “Inconsequential Arbitrage,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 34, Vol. 4, 2000, pp. 439-469.
[5] N. Kuksin, “General Equilibrium: Arbitrage and Information,” Centre for Economic Reform and Transformation Discussion Paper No. 701, Heriot Watt University, Edinburgh, 2007.
[6] G. Cassel, “The World’s Monetary Problems,” Constable and Company, London, 1921.
[7] R. Roll, “Violations of Purchasing Power Parity and Their Implications for Efficient International Commodity Markets,” In: M. Sarnat and G. Szego, Eds., International Finance and Trade, Vol. 1, Ballinger Pub. Co., Cambridge, 1979, pp. 133-176.
[8] F. Modigliani and M. H. Miller, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment,” American Economic Review, Vol. 48, No. 3, l958, pp. 26l 297.
[9] F. Modigliani and M. H. Miller, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment: Re- ply,” American Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 4, 1959, pp. 655 667.
[10] S. A. Ross, “The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 13, No. 3, 1976, pp. 341-360. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(76)90046-6
[11] R. Roll and S. A. Ross, “An Empirical Investigation of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 35, No. 5, 1980, pp. 1073-1103.
[12] O. Varela and R. E. Olson, “A General Equilibrium Analysis of Financial Regulation,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 30, No. 3, 1986, pp. 329-340. doi:10.1016/0047-2727(86)90054-X
[13] O. Varela, “Firms’ Factor Cost Responses to the Modigliani-Miller Propositions,” Review of Business and Economic Research, Vol. 22, No. 1, 1986, pp. 55-68.
[14] R. W. Jones, “The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 73, No. 6, 1965, pp. 557 572.
[15] R. N. Batra, “Studies in the Pure Theory of International Trade,” St. Martin’s Press, New York, 1973.
[16] T. B. Rybczynski, “Factor Endowment and Relative Commodity Prices,” Economica, Vol. 22, No. 88, 1955, pp. 336-341. doi:10.2307/2551188
[17] W. Stolper and P. Samuelson, “Protection and Real Wages,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 1, 1941, pp. 58-73. doi:10.2307/2967638

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.