Put Options with Linear Investment for Hull-White Interest Rates

Abstract

We derive a Put Option price associated with selling strategy of the underlying security in a random interest rate environment. This extends Put Option pricing under linear investment strategy from the Black-Scholes setting to Hull-White stochastic interest rate model. As an application, Call Option price for the linear investment strategy in the Hull-White model is established. Our results address recent emergence of developing dynamic investment strategies for the purpose of reducing the investor risk exposure associated with European-type options.

Share and Cite:

Korzeniowski, A. and Ghorbani, N. (2021) Put Options with Linear Investment for Hull-White Interest Rates. Journal of Mathematical Finance, 11, 152-162. doi: 10.4236/jmf.2021.111007.

1. Introduction

A steady growth of financial derivatives market over the past decades led to various generalizations of the classical Black-Scholes model. Notably, a pioneering work of Wang et al. ( [1] [2] [3] ) introduced a dynamic investing strategy in the underlying security for the purpose of hedging the investment risks. It turned out that selling a security proportionally to its dropping price for Put Option and buying the security proportionally to its rising price for Call Option (both under the Black-Scholes model) resulted in lower Option price. Zhang et al. [4] extended the result for Call Option to stochastic interest rates following the Vasicek model. Subsequently, Ghorbani and Korzeniowski [5] obtained the Call Option price with investment strategy for the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) interest rates model via path-integral representation based on n-dimensional Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. It is worth noting that unlike in the Vasicek model, where the interest rate is gaussian, the interest rate process in the CIR model is no longer gaussian and lacks the closed form representation.

The gist of considering dynamic investment strategies, such as presented here, is two-fold. Firstly, unlike in the classical Black-Scholes model where the investor buys options and has no position in the underlying stock throughout the option time horizon, the dynamic investment strategy requires the investor to continuously trade the stock, whereby lowering the investor risk which is manifested by the lower option price. Secondly, the interest rates are no longer constant and are assumed stochastic.

This paper is concerned with Put Option hedging by linear investment strategy under the Hull-White stochastic interest rates model. European Put Option with the linear investment strategy triggers stock selling whenever the stock price falls below the strike price and stays in the range [ ( 1 α ) K , K ] . Following [2] we state the relevant facts regarding the hedging strategy. The investment fraction is defined by:

Q ( S ) = { β S ( 1 α ) K ( 1 β ) α K [ S ( 1 α ) K ] + β ( 1 α ) K S K 1 S K (1.1)

where

S is stock price.

Q ( S ) is the stock investment proportion, which is equal to the value of the stock investment divided by A, where A is the entire investment amount.

K is strike price of the option.

α is the investment strategy index, indicating the stock investment occurs during the period in which the stock price drops from K to ( 1 α ) K .

β is the minimum value of the stock investment proportion.

It was found in [2] that the Put Option value VT based on the linear investment with parameters α , β , strike price K reads as follows:

V T = { 0 S T K 1 β α ( 2 α 1 2 K + ( 1 α ) S T S T 2 2 K ) ( 1 α ) K S T K ( K β S T ) ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 S T ( 1 α ) K (1.2)

where ST is the terminal stock price.

We will use the above formula for the stock price that satisfies a stochastic differential equation (SDE) with drift depending on the random interest rate, whose SDE follows the Hull-White model.

2. The Market Model

The evolution of the stock price S t satisfies the following SDE

d S t = μ t S t d t + σ 1 S t d W 1 , t (2.1)

with mean return μ t , constant volatility σ 1 and a standard Brownian motion W 1 , t . The stock price dynamic under the risk-neutral measure is then as follows

d S t = r t S t d t + σ 1 S t d W 1 , t (2.2)

where r t is the interest rate.

By Ito formula the stock price at time T can be expressed as

S T = S 0 e 0 T ( r s σ 1 2 2 ) d s + 0 T σ 1 d W 1 , t (2.3)

where S0 is the initial stock price.

Wang et al. [2] proposed a put option model based on a dynamic investment strategy for the Black-Scholes option pricing. In this paper we extend their result to the stochastic Hull-White interest rate model r t which satisfies the following SDE

d r t = ( θ ( t ) a r t ) d t + σ 2 d W 2 , t (2.4)

with a and σ 2 constants and W 2 , t standard Brownian motion independent from W 1 , t .

Remark 2.1. Special case of Hull-White model, θ ( t ) = a b , becomes the Vasicek model.

In general, Calin [6], θ ( t ) satisfies the following equation

θ ( t ) = t f ( 0 , t ) + a f ( 0 , t ) + σ 2 2 a ( 1 e 2 a t ) (2.5)

where f ( 0 , t ) is the yield curve determined by the bond price.

The solution to (2.4) reads

r t = r 0 e a t + e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s + σ 2 e a t 0 t e a s d W 2 , s . (2.6)

Note that the first two terms are deterministic and the last is a Wiener integral, thus the process r t is normally distributed, with mean and variance

E [ r t ] = r 0 e a t + e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s V a r [ r t ] = σ 2 2 2 a ( 1 e 2 a t ) (2.7)

Integrating (2.6) yields

0 t r s d s = r 0 ( 1 e a t ) a + 0 t e a s 0 s θ ( u ) e a u d u d s + σ 2 0 t e a s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u (2.8)

when the interest rates are stochastic, the bond price is calculated by conditional expectation

P ( t , T ) = E [ e t T r s d s | F t ] (2.9)

where F t denotes the information available in the market at time t.

Lemma 2.1. The Hull-White zero-coupon bond price is as follows

P ( 0 , T ) = e r 0 ( e a T 1 ) a 0 T e a s 0 s θ ( u ) e a u d u d s + σ 2 2 2 a 2 [ T + 1 e 2 a T 2 a 2 a ( 1 e a T ) ] (2.10)

Proof: By (2.9)

P ( 0 , T ) = E [ e 0 T r s d s | F 0 ] = e r 0 ( 1 e a T ) a e 0 T e a s 0 s θ ( u ) e a u d u d s E [ e σ 2 0 T e a s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u d s | F 0 ] (2.11)

The proof will be carried out in several steps.

Step 1: Set X T = 0 T e a s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u d s , then

E [ X T ] = o T e a s E [ 0 s e a u d W 2 , u ] d s = 0 (2.12)

since 0 s e a u d W 2 , u is gaussian with mean 0 and variance e 2 a s 1 2 a .

Step 2:

By product rule

d ( X s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u ) = 0 s e a u d W 2 , u d X s + X s d 0 s e a u d W 2 , u + d X s d 0 s e a u d W 2 , u 0 = e a s ( 0 s e a u d W 2 , u ) 2 d s + X s e a s d W 2 , s (2.13)

Integrating the above gives

X T 0 T e a s d W 2 , s = 0 T e a s ( 0 s e a u d W 2 , u ) 2 d s + 0 T X s e a s d W 2 , s (2.14)

By taking the expectation and using the fact that the Wiener integral has zero mean, we obtain

E [ X T 0 T e a s d W 2 , s ] = 0 T e a s E [ ( 0 T e a s d W 2 , s ) 2 ] d s = 0 T e a s ( e 2 a s 1 2 a ) d s = 1 a 2 ( e a T + e a T 2 1 ) (2.15)

Step 3: Applying Ito lemma:

d ( X T 2 ) = 2 X T d X T + ( d X T ) 2 = 2 X T e a T 0 T e a s d W 2 , s d t (2.16)

then integrating and applying step 2, yields

E [ X T 2 ] = 2 0 T e a s E [ X s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u ] d s = 2 a 2 0 T ( 1 + e 2 a s 2 e a s ) d s = 1 a 2 [ T + 1 2 a ( 1 e 2 a T ) + 2 a ( e a T 1 ) ] (2.17)

Step 4: Using a stochastic variant of Fubini’s theorem we interchange the Riemann and the Wiener integrals as follows

X T = 0 T e a s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u d s = 0 s e a u 0 T e a s d s d W 2 , u = 0 T e a s d s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u = 1 a ( 1 e a T ) 0 s e a u d W 2 , u (2.18)

which implies that XT is normally distributed with mean 0 and variance E [ X T 2 ] computed in step 3. Therefore

E [ e σ 2 0 T e a s 0 s e a u d W 2 , u d s ] = E [ e σ 2 X T ] = e ( σ 2 2 2 ) V a r ( X T ) = e σ 2 2 2 a 2 [ T + 1 e 2 a T 2 a 2 a ( 1 e a T ) ] (2.19)

which gives rise to the formula (zero coupon bond price).

3. Hull-White under T-Forward Measure

The stochastic model for the bond price under Hull-White model is as follows [6]

d P ( t , T ) = r t P ( t , T ) d t + ν ( t , T ) P ( t , T ) d W t r t P ( t , T ) d t σ 2 a ( 1 e a ( T t ) ) P ( t , T ) d W t (3.1)

In order to simplify the calculation of option value under the stochastic interest rate, we use the technique of changing the measure and numeraire. Following general considerations in Brigo and Mercurio [7] the dynamic of Hull-White model under the zero-coupon bond as numeraire can be obtained using the following

Proposition 2.3.1. [7] Assume two numeraires B and P evolve under a probability measure Q

d B t = ( ... ) d t + σ t B d W t d P t = ( ... ) d t + σ t P d W t (3.2)

Then the drift of process X under numeraire P is

μ t P ( X t ) = μ t B ( X t ) σ t ( X t ) ( σ t B B t σ t P P t ) (3.3)

and

d W t P = d W t + ( σ t B B t σ t P P t ) d t . (3.4)

Note. By the Proposition for money market account d B t = r t B t d t and zero-coupon bond d P ( t , T ) = r t P ( t , T ) d t σ a ( 1 e a ( T t ) ) P ( t , T ) d W 2 , t , r t for Hull-White model under T-forward measure Q T satisfies the following SDE

d r t = ( θ ( t ) a r t σ 2 2 a ( 1 e a ( T t ) ) ) d t + σ d W t T (3.5)

where

d W t T = d W t + σ a ( 1 e a ( T t ) ) d t . (3.6)

Now that we obtained the evolution of Hull-White under T-forward measure, we solve (3.5) via multiplying by the integrating factor e a t to get

d ( r t e a t ) = e a t θ ( t ) d t e a t σ 2 2 a ( 1 e a ( T t ) ) d t + e a t σ 2 d W 2 , t T . (3.7)

Integrating from 0 and t yields

r t = r 0 e a t σ 2 2 a [ ( e a t 1 ) e a T ( 2 e a T e a t 1 ) 2 a ] e a t + e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s + σ 2 0 t e a ( t s ) d W 2 , s T (3.8)

By integrating over [0, T] we obtain

0 T r t d t = r 0 1 e a T a σ 2 2 a [ e 2 a T ( ( 2 a T 3 ) e 2 a T + 4 e a T 1 ) 2 a 2 ] + 0 T e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s d t + σ 2 0 T 0 t e a ( t s ) d W 2 , u T d t . (3.9)

4. Put Option Price

The Put Option price is expressed as a product of the expectation of VT under the T-forward measure and the price of zero-coupon bond. Notice that by (2.3) stock price ST is lognormally distributed and we denote its probability density by f ( s ) for S T = s .

Theorem 4.1. (Put Option Price). The Put Option price at time 0 under the Hull-White interest rate is given by

P T = P ( 0 , T ) ( ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) N [ d 1 ] β e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 N [ d 2 ] ) P ( 0 , T ) ( 1 β α 2 α 1 2 K [ N ( d 3 ) N ( d 1 ) ] ) P ( 0 , T ) ( 1 β α ( 1 α ) e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 [ N ( d 4 ) N ( d 2 ) ] ) + P ( 0 , T ) ( β 1 2 α K e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 [ N ( d 4 ) N ( d 2 ) ] ) (4.1)

where

P ( 0 , T ) = e r 0 ( e a T 1 ) a 0 T e a s 0 s θ ( u ) e a u d u d s + σ 2 2 2 a 2 [ T + 1 e 2 a T 2 a 2 a ( 1 e a T ) ]

d 1 = ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T d 2 = ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T 2 σ T d 3 = ln K μ T σ T d 4 = ln K μ T σ T 2 σ T μ T = ln S 0 σ 1 2 2 T + r 0 1 e a T a σ 2 2 a [ e 2 a T ( ( 2 a T 3 ) e 2 a T + 4 e a T 1 ) 2 a 2 ] + 0 T e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s d t σ T 2 = σ 1 2 T + σ 2 a 2 [ T 2 1 e a T a + 1 e 2 a T 2 a ]

Proof.

E T [ V T ] = 0 ( 1 α ) K [ ( K β S T ) ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ] f ( S T ) d S T + ( 1 α ) K K 1 β α [ 2 α 1 2 K + ( 1 α ) S T S T 2 2 K ] f ( S T ) d S T = 0 ( 1 α ) K [ ( K β S T ) ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ] f ( S T ) d S T + ( 1 α ) K K 1 β α [ 2 α 1 2 K + ( 1 α ) S T ] f ( S T ) d S T ( 1 α ) K K [ 1 β α S T 2 2 K ] f ( S T ) d S T (4.2)

We split evaluating E T [ V T ] into integrals I 1 , I 2 and I 3 as follows

I 1 = 0 ( 1 α ) K [ ( K β S T ) ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ] f ( S T ) d S T I 2 = ( 1 α ) K K 1 β α [ 2 α 1 2 K + ( 1 α ) S T ] f ( S T ) d S T I 3 = ( 1 α ) K K [ 1 β α S T 2 2 K ] f ( S T ) d S T (4.3)

Set y = ln S T , then f ( e y ) e y is the probability density function of ln S T , and the mean and variance under the T-forward measure can be expressed form (2.3) as follows

μ T = E T [ ln S T ] = E T [ ln S 0 + 0 T ( r t σ 1 2 2 ) d t + 0 T σ 1 d W 1 , t T ] = ln S 0 σ 1 2 2 T + E T [ 0 T r t d t ] + E T [ 0 T σ 1 d W 1 , t T ] 0 = ln S 0 σ 1 2 2 T + r 0 1 e a T a σ 2 2 a [ e 2 a T ( ( 2 a T 3 ) e 2 a T + 4 e a T 1 ) 2 a 2 ] + 0 T e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s d t (4.4)

σ T 2 = V a r T [ ln S T ] = V a r T [ ln S 0 + 0 T ( r t σ 1 2 2 ) d t + 0 T σ 1 d W 1 , t T ] = V a r T [ ln S 0 ] + V a r T [ 0 T ( r t σ 1 2 2 ) d t ] + V a r T [ 0 T σ 1 d W 1 , t T ] = V a r T [ 0 T σ 1 d W 1 , t T ] + V a r T [ 0 T σ 2 e a t 0 t e a s d W 2 , s T d t ] = 0 T σ 1 2 d t + V a r T [ σ 2 0 T 0 t e a ( t s ) d W 2 , s T d t ] = σ 1 2 T + σ 2 a 2 [ T 2 1 e a T a + 1 e 2 a T 2 a ] . (4.5)

Moreover, we have

f ( e y ) e y = 1 2 π σ T e 1 2 ( y μ T ) 2 σ T 2 (4.6)

and therefore

I 1 = 0 ( 1 α ) K ( ( K β S T ) ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) f ( S T ) d S T = 0 ( 1 α ) K ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) f ( S T ) d S T β 0 ( 1 α ) K S T f ( S T ) d S T = ln ( 1 α ) K ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) f ( e y ) e y d y β ln ( 1 α ) e y f ( e y ) e y d y = ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) 1 2 π σ T ln ( 1 α ) K e 1 2 ( y μ T ) 2 σ T 2 d y β 1 2 π σ T ln ( 1 α ) K e y e 1 2 ( y μ T ) 2 σ T 2 d y

Setting z = y μ T σ T gives

I 1 = ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T e 1 2 z 2 d z β 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T e μ T + z σ T e 1 2 z 2 d z = ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T e 1 2 z 2 d z β 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 e 1 2 ( z σ T 2 ) d z = ( K ( 1 β ) K ( 2 α ) 2 ) N [ ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T ] β e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 N [ ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T 2 σ T ] (4.7)

where N ( x ) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function.

Similarly,

I 2 = ( 1 α ) K K 1 β α ( 2 α 1 2 K + ( 1 α ) S T ) f ( S T ) d S T = ( 1 α ) K K ( 1 β α 2 α 1 2 K ) f ( S T ) d S T + 1 β α ( 1 α ) ( 1 α ) K K S T f ( S T ) d S T = 1 β α 2 α 1 2 K ln ( 1 α ) K ln K f ( e y ) e y d y + 1 β α ( 1 α ) ln ( 1 α ) K ln K e y f ( e y ) e y d y = 1 β α 2 α 1 2 K 1 2 π σ T ln ( 1 α ) K ln K e 1 2 ( y μ T ) 2 σ T 2 d y + 1 β α ( 1 α ) 1 2 π σ T ln ( 1 α ) K ln K e y e 1 2 ( y μ T ) 2 σ T 2 d y

= 1 β α 2 α 1 2 K 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T ln K μ T σ T e 1 2 z 2 d z + 1 β α ( 1 α ) 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T ln K μ T σ T e μ T + z σ T e 1 2 z 2 d z = 1 β α 2 α 1 2 K [ N ( ln K μ T σ T ) N ( ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T ) ] + 1 β α ( 1 α ) e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 [ N ( ln K μ T σ T 2 σ T ) N ( ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T 2 σ T ) ] (4.8)

and

I 3 = ( 1 α ) K K [ 1 β α S T 2 2 K ] f ( S T ) d S T = β 1 2 α K ( 1 α ) K K S T 2 f ( S T ) d S T = β 1 2 α K ln ( 1 α ) K ln K e 2 y f ( e y ) d y = β 1 2 α K ln ( 1 α ) K ln K e y e y f ( e y ) d y = β 1 2 α K 1 2 π σ T ln ( 1 α ) K ln K e y e 1 2 ( y μ T 2 ) σ T 2 d y = β 1 2 α K 1 2 π ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T ln K μ T σ T e μ T + z σ T e 1 2 z 2 d z = β 1 2 α K e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 [ N ( ln K μ T σ T 2 σ T ) N ( ln ( 1 α ) K μ T σ T 2 σ T ) ] (4.9)

Corollary. 4.1. (Put Option price for Vasicek Model). Observe that in the special case we recover the Put Option price for the Vasicek model when θ ( t ) = a b .

5. Application to Call Option

European Call Option under the linear investment strategy triggers stock buying whenever the stock price exceeds the strike price. The investment fraction is defined by:

Q ( S ) = { 0 S K β α K ( S K ) K S ( 1 + α ) K β S ( 1 + α ) K

where

S is stock price.

Q ( S ) is the stock investment proportion, which is equal to the value of the stock investment divided by A, where A is the entire investment amount.

K is strike price of the option.

α is the investment strategy index, indicating the stock investment occurs during the period in which the stock price increases fromK to ( 1 + α ) K .

β is the maximum value of the stock investment proportion.

Zhang et al. [4] derived the Call Option price C C T based on the linear investment for the Vasicek interest rate model and we extend their result to the Hull-White model.

Theorem. 5.1. The Call Option price with the linear investment strategy at time 0 for the Hull-White model is given by

C T = P ( 0 , T ) ( 1 + β α ( 1 μ T + ln K σ T 2 ) ) e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 [ N ( d 1 ) N ( d 2 ) ] P ( 0 , T ) ( 1 + β α ) K [ N ( d 3 ) N ( d 4 ) ] P ( 0 , T ) β α σ T 2 π e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 ( e d 2 2 2 e d 1 2 2 ) + P ( 0 , T ) ( 1 β α ln ( 1 + α ) ) e μ T + 1 2 σ T 2 N ( d 1 ) + P ( 0 , T ) K ( β 1 ) N ( d 3 )

with P ( 0 , T ) , d 1 , d 2 , d 3 , d 4 , μ T and σ T 2 defined below

P ( 0 , T ) = e r 0 ( e a T 1 ) a 0 T e a s 0 s θ ( u ) e a u d u d s + σ 2 2 2 a 2 [ T + 1 e 2 a T 2 a 2 a ( 1 e a T ) ] d 1 = ln ( 1 + α ) K μ T σ T 2 σ T d 2 = ln K μ T σ T 2 σ T d 3 = ln ( 1 + α ) K μ T σ T d 4 = ln K μ T σ T μ T = ln S 0 σ 1 2 2 T + r 0 1 e a T a σ 2 2 a [ e 2 a T ( ( 2 a T 3 ) e 2 a T + 4 e a T 1 ) 2 a 2 ] + 0 T e a t 0 t θ ( s ) e a s d s d t σ T 2 = σ 1 2 T + σ 2 a 2 [ T 2 1 e a T a + 1 e 2 a T 2 a ]

Proof. The formula for CT has been derived in Zhang et al. [4] for the Vasicek model with explicit dependence on the bond price P ( 0 , T ) , μ T and σ T 2 . Since in the Hull-White model the respective bond price P ( 0 , T ) , μ T and σ T 2 have been found in (2.10), (4.4) and (4.5) respectively, and the derivation of the Call Option price CT in Hull-White model is analogous to that of Vasicek model we omit the proof of the formula CT.

Corollary. 5.1. (Call Option price for Vasicek Model). Observe that in the special case we recover the Call Option price for the Vasicek model when θ ( t ) = a b .

6. Conclusion

We obtained the closed form of the Put and Call Option price for the linear investment strategy under the Hull-White stochastic interest rates. In particular, a protective put option can serve as an insurance policy against losses for the stock holder. Since the option price associated with trading of the underlying security is based on continuous stock trading (impossible to implement!), a feasible discrete variant is in order. Recently Li et al. [8] proposed a discretized method for the Call Option under the classical Black-Scholes with linear investment strategy. A feasible market implementation for our Hull-White pricing model will be presented in a forthcoming paper. Regarding the subject of dynamic investment strategies for European-type options under stochastic interest rates, to the best of our knowledge, the references cited in this article include up to date published research.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] Wang, X.F. and Wang, L. (2007) Study on Black-Scholes Stock Option Pricing Model Based on Investment Strategy. International Journal of Innovative Computing, Information and Control, 3, 1755-1780.
https://doi.org/10.1109/WICOM.2007.1020
[2] Wang, X., Wang, L. and Zhai, A. (2007) Research on the Black-Scholes Stock Put Option Model Based on Dynamic Investment Strategy. 2007 International Conference on Wireless Communications, Networking and Mobile Computing, Shanghai, 21-25 September 2007, 4128-4131. https://doi.org/10.1109/WICOM.2007.1020
[3] Wang, X.F. and Wang, L. (2009) Study on Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model Based on General Linear Investment Strategy. International Journal of Innovative Computing, Information and Control, 5, 2188.
[4] Zhang, X., Shu, H.S., Kan, X., Fang, Y.Y. and Zheng, Z.W. (2018) The Call Option Pricing Based on Investment Strategy with Stochastic Interest Rate. Journal of Mathematical Finance, 8, 43-57. https://doi.org/10.4236/jmf.2018.81004
[5] Ghorbani, N. and Korzeniowski, A. (2020) Adaptive Risk Hedging for Call Options under Cox-Ingersoll-Ross Interest Rates. Journal of Mathematical Finance, 10, 697-704.
https://doi.org/10.4236/jmf.2020.104040
[6] Calin, O. (2016) Deterministic and Stochastic Topics in Computational Finance, World Scientific, Princeton, NJ, USA. https://doi.org/10.1142/10341
[7] Brigo, D. and Mercurio, F. (2006) Interest Rate Models-Theory and Practice, with Smile, Inflation and Credit. 2nd Edition, Springer, Finance, 23-47.
[8] Li, M., Wang, X. and Sun, F. (2019) Pricing of Proactive Hedging European Option with Dynamic Discrete Strategy. Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, 2019, Article ID 1070873. https://doi.org/10.1155/2019/1070873

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.