The Evaluation of Dexterity and a Theory of the Growth of a Firm ()
1. Introduction
The investment function theory relies heavily on the existence of the adjustment function. Uzawa [3] considers how the quality of installed real capital within a firm utterly differs from the new capital sold in the market. Real capital is assumed to become productive only via the adjustment process. He defines the ability of adjustment as a management skill (Penrose effect).
However, components of adjustment costs are quite ambiguous. Why do automatic changes in the quality of real capital necessarily incur adjustment costs? It would seem natural that the dexterity of employees contributes to increasing the capacity of real capital. The intangible human capital that employees accumulate plays a crucial role in the growth of a firm. In other words, it is a quite important factor for the growth of a firm to internalize a positive externality from skilled labor to capital via the formal/informal education.
Once we admit such a fact, it is plausible to regard labor as the quasi-fixed production factor instead of real capital. The growth of a firm is the equivalent to that of employees’ skills, thus, we should replace the investment function theory with the theory of human capital accumulation.
Such a reconstruction of the investment theory facilitates the economic interpretation of the adjustment cost function. The additional costs necessary for a firm’s growth are the costs of the education that are needed to enhance and/or furnish the human capital held by employees. In addition to reconstruction, we shall establish human-capital’s q theory, corresponding to Tobin’s [1] q theory concerning real-capital accumulation.
Moreover, we shall consider the case that such internalization does not work well. In this case, an employer neglects the existence of the important intangible asset (i.e., the dexterity) and regards his firm as being entirely constructed by marketable and substitutable capitals as elementary neoclassical theory of production assumes.
In such situation, the employer recognizes that his production opportunity faces the diminishing return to scale because the important production factor (i.e., the dexterity) lacks from his perspective. The surplus gained from the dexterity is regards as an autonomous technological progress (a kind of good will) whose return should be attributed to him.
Since the recognized production function is diminishing return to scale and the optimal size of a firm exists, we easily show that the equilibrium growth rate of such a type of firm is zero in the long run. That is, how efficiently to internalize the accumulation of the intangible asset determines whether a firm can continue to grow.
The contents of the article are as follows. In Section 2, we construct a dynamic theory of human-capital accumulation, that is, human-capital’s q theory. Section 3 considers the importance of internalization of employees’ dexterity for promoting the growth of a firm. Section 4 gives brief concluding remarks.
2. The Model
There are employees, who are equally talented, with a fixed continuum density [0,1] at the start of an economy. To avoid the unemployment problem, we assume that full-employment has been attained1. There is also a single perishable good that can not only be consumed but also be used for the formal and/or informal education of employees.
We consider the problem how the correct evaluation of employees’ dexterity contributes to the economic wellbeing. An elementary calculus of variation is deployed for solving such a problem.
The lifetime utility function of each employee is
(1)
where denotes the consumption level at time, and is the time preference rate.
Using Otaki and Yaginuma [5], we specify the production function as follows.
(2)
where is a linear homogenous function that represents the effective capital input. and denote the volume of output and the deployed real capital used for it, respectively. is the labor input in terms of efficiency units. In addition, we assume is also linear homogenous.
The economic meaning of Equation (2) is as follows. As well as the increment in output owing to real capital
, an improvement of the efficiency unit of the skilled labor force brings about two positive effects. One is direct, in the sense that employees become able to deal with the procedures involved in their jobs more efficiently
. The other is indirect, as real capital works more productively due to the dexterity of a skilled labor force
.
We regard the internalization of the second effect as meaning that the appropriate enhancement of employees’ dexterity is the raison d’ tre of a firm. Elementary economics deploys the linear homogenous production function, and so excludes an externality such as
from labor to capital, and thus, a firm can ultimately be decomposed into these two production resources. As Coase [6] suggests, such a firm without the externality, can only be constructed by assembling production resources. Hence, this cannot explain how an organization is differentiated from the market.
Whereas what it is that differentiates a firm from the market is quite ambiguous in Coase-Tobin-Uzawa theory, we emphasize that the substance of a firm is determined by the inseparability of labor and capital originating from employees’ dexterity, namely, the externality from labor to capital.
Net cash flow per employee, which in our setting is always equal to current consumption can be written as
(3)
where denotes the growth rate of the efficiency of labor. is the educational cost function of heightening dexterity; this corresponds to the adjustment cost function (the Penrose function) in Tobin-Uzawa theory.
Taking the linear homogeneity of F and into consideration, from the short-run maximization decision for, the Euler theorem transforms Equation (3) into
(4)
From Equations (1) and (4), the objective function of a representative firm becomes
(5)
It is well-known that under such a linear homogenous environment, the only optimum path of involves a growth rate that is constant over time, hence, Equation (5) is rewritten by
(6)
Thus, by differentiating Equation (6) with respect to g, we obtain the optimal skill accumulation rate as
(7)
Similar to Uzawa [3] in the case of real capital accumulation, the right-hand side of Equation (7) expresses human-capital’s q, which corresponds to the shadow price of an employee measured by the efficiency unit, and thus, this equation implicitly defines q theory of the human-capital investment. Hence, it is also clear that the following theorem holds from Equations (5) and (7):
Theorem 1 The equilibrium lifetime utility per capita is represented by
(8)
Equation (8) succinctly shows that the lifetime utility per employee is equal to the product of his human-capital’s q and accumulated skills.
In addition, the equilibrium growth rate of an employee’s skills g* is defined by Equation (7).
3. Dexterity as the Engine for the Growth of a Firm
In above section, we assume that a firm can fully internalize the dexterity of employees. However, such a mechanism works only when the employer can properly evaluate each employee’s performance. It implies that employees are non-anonymous within the firm. This nonanonymity characterizes the difference between the transaction inside and outside firm (i.e., market transaction).
When an employer does not concern with the dexterity of employees and deals with them anonymously as the standard neoclassical-type firm, such internalization is not possible. As the production (2) reveals, the employer fails to count the externality emerging from the dexterity of employees in such situation. He misinterprets the progress of productivity due to the dexterity as the autonomous progress which is independent of employees’ skills.
The first-order conditions for maximization problem of such type of firm are
(9)
where w denotes the market real wage for unskilled workers. denotes the conditional labor demand function in the sense that the contribution of dexterity is fixed to L*, means the optimal value.
From Euler’s theorem and Equation (9), we obtain
(10)
Equation (10) implies that an employer, who does not evaluate the contribution of dexterity to the production process, recognizes that his production function is diminishing return to scale2. The optimal firm size is determined by Equation (9). This implies that the growth rate of such a firm diminishes into zero in the long run.
Above discussion leads us to the following theorem.
Theorem 2 If an employer does not concern with the development of employees’ dexterity, then, he rationally interprets that his production function is diminishing return to scale. Hence, there is no opportunity of growth for such a firm in the long run. In this sense, whether a firm can continue to grow crucially depends on how efficiently to internalize the dexterity. In other words, the correct evaluation of the dexterity is the engine for the growth of a firm.
4. Concluding Remarks
This article has considered the role of employees’ dexterity in the growth of a firm. The dexterity is represented by a positive externality from skilled labor force to real capital within a firm. The obtained results are as follows: First, when an employer succeeds in internalizing such an externality, he can perceive that his production function is constant return to scale, and thus find the infinite opportunity for the growth of his firm. In relation to this human-capital investment, we have developed the concept of human-capital’s q, replacing Tobin’s q (Tobin [1]), which puts too much importance on a kind of vintage effect concerning real capital (Uzawa [3]).
Second, we have clarified the reason why the adjustment-cost function (Penrose function) exists. While Uzawa’s interpretation is quite ambiguous as he did not expose the mechanism by which real capital is made productive, we suggest that the convex adjustment function expresses the non-negligible informal and/or formal educational costs for nurturing the various skills of employees.
Finally, we have proved that the production function becomes decreasing return to scale and overlooks the opportunity of the growth of a firm whenever an employer fails to internalize the dexterity. Such inefficiency comes from the fact that the employer confuses the surplus derived from the dexterity with the good will of his firm. Although it is an intangible asset, the dexterity is the embedded engine for the growth of a firm.
NOTES
2It is necessary and sufficient condition for a diminishing return to scale production function G that there is a non-negative and strictly increase function Φ such as
where λ is a non-negative number and y is the output. Function Φ represents the seriousness of diminishing return to scale. Differentiating both sides of above equation with respect to λ and applying the Euler’s theorem, we obtain
Thus, if the right-hand side of above equation is positive, such a production function is diminishing return to scale.