A Matching Model on the Use of Immigrant Social Networks and Referral Hiring

Abstract

Using a simple search model, with urn-ball derived matching function, this paper investigates the effect of firm owner’s and coworkers’ nativity on hiring patterns and wages. In the model, social networks reduce search frictions and wages are derived endogenously as a function of the efficiency of the social ties of current employees. As a result, individuals with more efficient connections tend to receive higher wages and lower unemployment rate. However, because this efficiency depends on matching with same-type owners and coworkers, there is also a differential effect among workers’ wages in the same firm. This analysis highlights the potential importance of social connections and social capital for understanding employment opportunities and wage differentials between these groups.

Share and Cite:

M. García-Pérez, "A Matching Model on the Use of Immigrant Social Networks and Referral Hiring," Theoretical Economics Letters, Vol. 2 No. 4, 2012, pp. 379-384. doi: 10.4236/tel.2012.24070.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] I. Light, “Deflecting Immigration,” Sage Publications, New York, 2006.
[2] J. R. Elliot, “Referral Hiring and Ethnically Homogeneous Jobs: How Prevalent Is the Connection and for Whom?” Social Science Research, Vol. 94, No. 3, 2001, pp. 426-454.
[3] M. Granovetter, “Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers,” The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1995.
[4] S. J. Curtis and J. T. Warner, “Matchmaker, Matchmaker: The Effect of Old Boy Networks on Job Match Quality, Earnings, and Tenure,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 10, No. 3, 1992, pp. 306-330. doi:10.1086/298289
[5] H. Holzer, “Hiring Procedures in the Firm: Their Economic Determinants and Outcomes,” NBER working paper series, 1987. http://www.nber.org/papers/w2185
[6] J. Montgomery, “Social Networks and Labor Market Out- comes: Toward an Economic Analysis,” American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 5, 1991, pp. 408-418.
[7] J. M. Abowd, F. Kramarz and D. N. Margolis. “High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms,” Econometrica, Vol. 67, No. 2, 1999, pp. 251-333. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00020
[8] E. L. Groshen, “Five Reasons Why Wages Vary among Employers,” Industrial Relations, Vol. 30, No. 3, 1991, pp. 350-381. doi:10.1111/j.1468-232X.1991.tb00793.x
[9] E. L. Groshen, “Sources of Intra-Industry Wage Dispersion: How Much Do Employers Matter?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, No. 3, August 1991, pp. 869-884. doi:10.2307/2937931
[10] R. Waldinger, “Black-Immigrant Competition Re-Assessed: New Evidence from Los Angeles,” Sociological Perspectives, Vol. 40, No. 3, 1997, pp. 365-386.
[11] A. Calvo-Armengol and M. O. Jackson, “The Effects of Social Networks on Employment and Inequality,” American Economic Review, Vol. 94, No. 3, 2004, pp. 426-454. doi:10.1257/0002828041464542
[12] A. Calvo-Armengol and M. O. Jackson, “Networks in Labor Markets: Wage and Employment Dynamics and Inequality,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 132, No. 1, 2007, pp. 27-46. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2005.07.007
[13] F. Fontaine, “A Simple Matching Model with Social Networks,” Economic Letters, Vol. 32, No. 4, 2006, pp. 1667-1717.
[14] J. W. Albrecht, G. Pieter and S. B. Vroman, “Matching with Multiple Applications,” Economic Letters, Vol. 78, No. 1, 2003, pp. 67-70. doi:10.1016/S0165-1765(02)00178-7

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.