
F. HESPELER
48
only imply real solutions, no further conditions beyond
the fact that all degrees of freedom must be restricted to
the real domain, are needed.
The paper is organized as follows. After this section’s
introduction section 2 presents the general method to be
employed. In sections 3 and 4 separate algebraic condi-
tions are developed which need to hold simultaneously in
order to guarantee a pure real-valued solutions. Section 5
concludes.
2. General Method
According to the solution algorithms for linear dynamic
models involving rational expectations, i.e.,
1
1
1
=
tt
tt
tt
vv
z
ww
GHCG
(1)
presented in [4,5,6-10], among others, any solution to
this type of models can be written in form of a VAR(1)-
process
1
122
=1
1
= .
tt
tqt
q
tt
vv
zE
ww
T
tq
z
(2)
Herein denotes the vector of endogenous
variables in period , while is an exogenous shock
vector realized in period . 1t
TT
tt
vw tt
z
t
is the vector of expec-
tational errors in the endogenous variables denoting the
difference between the unconditionally expected values
based on information available in period and the val-
ues actually realized in period . The shock vector
t might display some autocorrelation which explains
the appearance of expected future shock terms in Equa-
tion (2). In addition, the model in Equation (1) might be
required to fulfill the transversality condition
t
1t
z
>
=0.
lim tq
t
qtq
v
Ew
W (3)
Herein t denotes the operator for the unconditional
expectations based on information available in t. As
pointed out in [9] this requirement, if not guaranteed by
appropriate initial conditions, essentially restricts the
growth of the model’s unstable exogenous variables.
E
Depending on the characteristics of the used solution
method the coefficients 1 are defined as spe-
cific functions of the original coefficient matrices. The
central idea of asserting a real-valued solution starts with
the fact that often some of the coefficients are real by
construction. This claim will be discussed in the next
section for coefficients associated with the endogenous
variables and the expectational error terms. Afterwards it
will be analyzed with respect to the coefficient of the
exogenous shock term in the subsequent section. For any
coefficient for which this claim does not hold, we will
use any available degrees of freedom within that coeffi-
cient in order to force it into the real domain. Thus the
indeterminacy allows to guarantee a purely real-valued
solution for the model. Therefore such a coefficient
(,, )
will be decomposed into potentially complex,
, and
real, i.e.
, factors. The product of this factors has the
form
(() ())=()()i i
i1
(4)
where denotes the square root of , while
(
)
denotes the real (imaginary) part of its argument. When-
ever the last summand contains enough degrees of free-
dom in order to be forced down to zero, the entire coeffi-
cient will take on values from the set of real numbers.
Thus the entire solution of the macroeconomic model
will not include any complex numbers.
As already indicated the paper restricts the analysis on
the case of solution methods based on the generalized
Schur decomposition. Nevertheless, similar arguments
could be obtained for the case of solution methods based
on eigenvalue decompositions, Jordan decompositions
and ordinary Schur decompositions. This paper focuses
on the generalized Schur decomposition, because models
which can be solved by those methods nest all models
solvable by the mentioned alternative decompositions.
In addition the paper distinguishes two approaches to
balance the distorting influence of expectational errors
appearing within any rational expectations model. The
first approach has been presented in [8] and [10]. Herein
the mentioned distortion is eliminated by explaining the
expectational error’s influence on the model’s stable part
as a function of it’s influence on the model’s unstable
part, which itself is forced to be zero by the initial condi-
tions. On the other hand [5] explains the expectational
error directly as function of the exogenous shock term.
As shown in [2] this does not exclude sunspot solutions
because expectations might be driven by an additional
component which do not contribute to the model’s un-
stable part. For both approaches we also separate be-
tween the cases in which either a microfoundated trans-
versality condition is explicitly integrated into the solu-
tion as presented in [3] or the transversality condition is
only used in the traditional manner, e.g. [4], by forcing
the non-state variables to take on appropriate initial val-
ues.
3. Real-Valued Coefficients for Endogenous
Variables and Expectational Errors
In order to prove the claim that the coefficient of the en-
dogenous variables as well as those of the expectational
errors do not include complex numbers, some properties
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. TEL