Theoretical Economics Letters
Vol.08 No.11(2018), Article ID:86476,13 pages
10.4236/tel.2018.811138

Conservation of Capital: Homeomorphic Mapping from Intangible Aggregate Macro-Economic CDR Space into Tangible Micro-Economic Production Spaces

Dennis Ridley1,2*, Pierre Ngnepieba3

1School of Business & Industry, Florida A & M University, Tallahassee, FL, USA

2Department of Scientific Computing, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL, USA

3Department of Mathematics, Florida A & M University, Tallahassee, FL, USA

Copyright © 2018 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY 4.0).

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Received: July 3, 2018; Accepted: August 3, 2018; Published: August 6, 2018

ABSTRACT

The parsimonious capitalism, democracy, rule of law (CDR) growth model is the first global time invariant cross country model. It is the first to incorporate aggregate exogenous and endogenous sources of capital into a model for converting capital to real gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity. Aggregate capital is distributed to micro-economic units of production. This mapping is shown to be homeomorphic from intangible aggregate macro-economic CDR space into tangible micro-economic production spaces, such that under certain prescribed conditions capital is conserved.

Keywords:

CDR Index, GDP, Capitalism, Democracy, Rule of Law, Entrepreneurship

1. Introduction

A number of classical, neo-classical and modern economic growth models have been presented over time. The first model to include entrepreneurship was presented by Schumpeter [1] [2] [3] . Solow [4] [5] presented a neoclassical aggregate production function that has been widely adopted by economists. His adaptation of the Cobb-Douglas [6] production function is based on fixed capital. But, it does not include human capital ideas of imagination and creativity and must come up short when accounting for the totality of capital and growth. Also, since the Solow growth model is a production function stated in the aggregate, it represents a fallacy of composition (Cohen and Harcourt [7] ). There is no such thing as an aggregate production function. There is no way around this obstacle. Houthakker [8] discusses some micro combinations and suggestions for their aggregation into industries. Leontief [9] proposed the fixed proportions production function. The purpose of this paper is to explore aggregation to a national level. We show that under certain abstract configurations of productions units, an aggregate production function that is equivalent to the sum of individual production units is theoretically possible. But, these configurations are limited, restrictive and short of a miracle, most unlikely to occur in practice.

A better way to capture total capitalization for explaining what is responsible for economic growth is the Ridley [10] [11] [12] [13] , Ridley, Davis and Korovyakovskaya [14] and Ridley and Khan [15] CDR growth model: g = f (C, D, R). It is the most recent heterodox model that shows that the way capital is converted to real gross domestic product (GDP) is the same all over the world. Essentially, the catalyst rule of law (R) attracts intangible capital (C), and the catalyst democracy (D) deploys it optimally to create tangible wealth in the form of products and services. The catalysis is as described by Berzelius [16] in that D and R speed up the C to GDP conversion process but are not themselves changed by the process. The purpose of this paper is to show how capital from the aggregate real gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity (G) can be distributed to micro-economic production units. These provide inputs per the Cobb-Douglas micro-economic stipulation. The outputs from the micro-economic units can then be summed to obtain a correct aggregate G. Finally, we show that these mappings from intangible aggregate macro-economic CDR space into tangible micro-economic production spaces are homeomorphic (Weisstein [17] ) such that under certain prescribed configurations of micro-economic production units, capital is conserved.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Because the CDR growth model is a heterodox model that is built on different assumptions and relationships, Section 2 provides unique definitions and specifications. Section 3 provides an account of the relationship between the CDR growth model and the Cobb-Douglas function. Section 4 examines the CDR Cobb-Douglas mapping. Section 5 provides conclusions and suggestions for future research.

2. Definitions and Specifications

Definitions

Entrepreneurship is the process of starting a business, typically a startup company offering an innovative product, process or service.

Capitalist is a person who deploys his or her personal capital so as to maximize his or her own benefit and includes all rational people.

Real gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity (G) is the net product or value added that equates to standard of living.

Capitalism (C) is the mechanism for the collection and assembly of capital, measured by total market capitalization that reflects entrepreneurship capital and capital stock.

Democracy (D) is the private work force idea participation and periodic election of public representatives, and catalyst for the process of generating G from C.

Rule of law (R) is the reverse of corruption, the protection of shareholder and other property rights, and catalyst for the attraction of C.

Corruption is the abuse of entrusted power for private gain and can be classified as grand, petty and political, depending on the amounts of money lost and the sector where it occurs.

Property (rights) is a legal expression of an economically meaningful consensus by people about assets, how they should be held, used and exchanged.

The CDR growth model was created in the search for a model that accounts for the annual contribution to real gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity (G). The objective was to create an index that can be used to calculate G for any year. To accomplish that the model variables G, C, D, R are standardized by linear transformation to ensure lower and upper bounds of 0 and 1. That way, CDR becomes an index for the estimation of G for any country by inverse transformation when the highest G and lowest G are known for the year (see appendix). The CDR index is calculated from published country market capitalization, ranking in democracy, and ranking in corruption (Goel, Mazhar and Nelson [18] , Czap and Nur-tegin [19] , see also Couttenier and Toubal [20] , López, et al. [21] ).

The global time invariant model is given as follows:

g = β 0 + β C C + β D D + β R R + β C D R C D R + β N N + ε

where all variables are standardized by linear transformation to ensure upper and lower bounds on 0 g , C , D , R , C D R , N 1 . Democracy and corruption are rank ordered, where the highest = 1 and the lowest = the number of countries. Rule of law is the opposite of corruption. See Appendix.

When estimated from data, we get the CDR index = 1.53C + 0.14D + 0.23R − 1.21C∙D∙R + 0.38N that comprises positive C, D and R effects and a negative interaction component due to friction from democracy that reduces G from what it might otherwise be if there were perfect agreement amongst decision contributors (Click here to download supplementary source data). There is only a small contribution from natural resources (N) in explaining the variation in g, and N is not a decision variable that is under the control of government. There is also the well-known Dutch disease from natural resources that can have positive or negative effects on wealth, depending on how the financial economy is managed (Auty [22] , Frankel [23] , Norman [24] , Sachs and Warner [25] , Ross [26] , Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian [27] , Humphreys [28] , van der Ploeg [29] , Wadho [30] , Ridley [12] ). Therefore, for the purpose of this discussion it can be omitted from the model and from the appellation CDR index. The CDR model was re-estimated for years 1995 to 2016 (see Appendix) with similar results with the conclusion that it is global time invariant.

3. Integrating the CDR and Cobb-Douglas Functions

In general, consider m countries, i = 1 , 2 , 3 , , m , where country i contains n i production units. The ith country G estimate is G ^ i = g ^ i (highest G-lowest G) + lowest G, where in equilibrium,

g ^ i = f ( C i , D i , R i ) = β ^ C C i + β ^ D D i + β ^ R R i + β ^ C D R C i D i R i .

Since there is no such thing as an aggregate production function (Cohen and Harcourt [7] ), production of G ^ i is obtained from the sum of n i micro-economic production units. Consider a deterministic Cobb-Douglas function v i j = f ( f i j G ^ i , L i j ) applied to the jth unit of production in the ith country, where existing capital stock K i j in the f ( K i j , L i j ) Cobb-Douglas function is replaced by capital representing the investment of the fraction f i j of G ^ i , L i j is the matching quantity of physical labor in person-hours per annum, and v i j is the annual value of production. All labor is identical in nature and functionality. This operating definition of homogenous labor is consistent with the original theory of comparative advantage (Ricardo [31] [32] ). Any human differences due to knowledge, experience and skills are transferred into production capacity of capital stock. Assuming constant returns to scale, then v i j = A i j ( f i j G ^ i ) α i j L i j 1 α i j , where A i j is the total factor productivity (efficiency) and α i j and 1 α i j are output elasticities of capital and labor respectively. The total monetary value of production for country i is given by

j = 1 n i v i j = j = 1 n i A i j ( f i j G ^ i ) α i j L i j 1 α i j .

The global monetary value of production of all m countries is therefore

i = 1 m j = 1 n i A i j ( f i j G ^ i ) α i j L i j 1 α i j .

Or, substituting for G ^ i ,

i = 1 m j = 1 n i A i j { f i j [ f ( C i , D i , R i ) ( highest G lowest G ) + lowest G ] } α i j L i j 1 α i j .

when the model exponents sum to one ( j = 1 n i α i j = 1 ), the production function is first-order homogeneous, which implies constant returns to scale. That is, if all inputs are scaled by a common factor greater than zero, output will be scaled by the same factor.

4. Homeomorphic Mapping

We now consider the case of a single country i containing n i perfectly efficient ( A i j = 1 , for all i, j) production units

f ( G ^ i ) = j = 1 n i ( f i j G ^ i ) α i j L i j 1 α i j .

Capital comprises ineffable human capital ideas of imagination and creativity, and capital stock sourced from human capital ideas of imagination and creativity occurring in a prior time period and learning by many human beings through training. Consider capital to be derived entirely from human capital. In the Cobb-Douglas function capital and labor are interchangeable substitutes. In some applications pure labor is treated as mindless and is utilized in much the same way that machines are utilized. On the other hand, consider capital to be such that it has the potential to replace pure corporeal labor in its totality. And, as the capital increases labor decreases. Then, there is an output for input-capital-only that is equal to an output for a particular capital-labor combination. That is, the inputs can be considered to come purely from capital. Consider three hypothetical cases as follows.

Case 1:

If capital in each production unit is represented in a single machine that can perform all the functions including labor so that no labor is required, then the value of production in country i is given by

f ( G ^ i ) = j = 1 n i ( f i j G ^ i ) α i j , where α i j = 1 , for all i, j,

= j = 1 n i f i j G ^ i

Since G ^ i is independent of j,

f ( G ^ i ) = ( j = 1 n i f i j ) G ^ i .

That is, f ( G ^ i ) = θ i G ^ i where θ i is constant.

Therefore, f is a linear function.

Moreover,

1) f is continuous;

2) f has a continuous inverse f 1 ( G ^ i ) = 1 θ i G ^ i .

Therefore, this G ^ i + f i j G ^ i + is a homeomorphic mapping, or bicontinuous or topological isomorphism. If 100% of capital is distributed to production units then θ i = 1 , and the total production from n i units is G ^ i which is equal to G ^ i obtained from the aggregate CDR function, and capital is conserved.

Case 2:

If capital in each production unit is represented in two machines where the first is a traditional machine and the second machine is a robot that performs the function of labor so that no labor is required, then if the capital distributed to the first machine is r 1 j G ^ i and the capital distribution to the second machine (robot) is r 2 j G ^ i , then the value of production in country i is given by

f ( G ^ i ) = j = 1 n i 2 ( r 1 j G ^ i ) α i j ( r 2 j G ^ i ) 1 α i j , where r 1 j + r 2 j = f i j

Rewriting,

f ( G ^ i ) = j = 1 n i 2 r 1 j α i j G ^ i α i j r 2 j 1 α i j G ^ i 1 α i j = j = 1 n i 2 r 1 j α i j r 2 j 1 α i j G ^ i

Since G ^ i does not depend on j,

f ( G ^ i ) = ( j = 1 n i 2 r 1 j α i j r 2 j 1 α i j ) G ^ i .

That is,

f ( G ^ i ) = θ i G ^ i where θ i is constant.

Therefore, f is a linear function.

Moreover,

1) f is continuous.

2) f has a continuous inverse f 1 ( G ^ i ) = 1 θ i G ^ i .

Therefore, this G ^ i + r 1 j G ^ i , r 2 j G ^ i + is a homeomorphic mapping, or bicontinuous or topological isomorphism. If 100% of capital is distributed to production units such that θ i = 1 , then the total production from n i units is G ^ i which is equal to G ^ i obtained from the aggregate CDR function, and capital is conserved.

For example if r 1 j = r 2 j = 0.5 f i j , then

θ i = j = 1 n i 2 ( 0.5 f i j ) α i j ( 0.5 f i j ) 1 α i j = j = 1 n i f i j = 1 .

Now, consider r 1 j = a f i j , r 2 j = b f i j , where a , b ( 0 , 1 ) such that a + b = 1 . Then

θ i = j = 1 n i 2 ( a f i j ) α i j ( b f i j ) 1 α i j ,

θ i = j = 1 n i 2 a α i j ( 1 a ) 1 α i j f i j ,

θ i = j = 1 n i 2 a α i j ( 1 a ) ( 1 a ) α i j f i j ,

θ i = j = 1 n i 2 ( 1 a ) ( a / ( 1 a ) ) α i j f i j .

Therefore, if 2 ( 1 a ) ( a / ( 1 a ) ) α i j = 1 , for all i, j, then θ i = j = 1 n i f i j = 1 , and

( a / ( 1 a ) ) α i j = 1 / 2 ( 1 a ) ,

α i j ln ( a / ( 1 a ) ) = ln ( 1 / 2 ( 1 a ) ) ,

α i j = ln ( 1 / 2 ( 1 a ) ) / ln ( a / ( 1 a ) ) .

Therefore, there are many combinations of r 1 j , r 2 j and α i j in which θ i = 1 and capital is conserved.

Case 3:

If capital in each production unit is represented in a single machine that can perform all the functions including labor so that no labor is required, and the production units are themselves complementary, then the value of production in country i is given by

f ( G ^ i ) = n i ( f i 1 G ^ i ) α i 1 ( f i 2 G ^ i ) α i 2 ( f i n i G ^ i ) α i n i , where j = 1 n i α i j = 1 .

Rewriting,

f ( G ^ i ) = n i j = 1 n i ( f i j G ^ i ) α i j = n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j G ^ i α i j = n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j j = 1 n i G ^ i α i j

Since G ^ i does not depend on j,

f ( G ^ i ) = ( n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j ) G ^ i α i 1 G ^ i α i 2 G ^ i α i n i = ( n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j ) G ^ i j = 1 n i α i j = ( n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j ) G ^ i since j = 1 n i α i j = 1.

That is,

f ( G ^ i ) = θ i G ^ i where θ i is constant.

Therefore, f is a linear function.

Moreover,

1) f is continuous.

2) f has a continuous inverse f 1 ( G ^ i ) = 1 θ i G ^ i .

Therefore, this G ^ i + f i j G ^ i + is a homeomorphic mapping, or bicontinuous or topological isomorphism. If 100% of capital is distributed to production units such that θ i = 1 , then the total production from n i units is G ^ i which is equal to G ^ i obtained from the aggregate CDR function, and capital is conserved.

For example, if f i j are distributed equally, such that f i j = 1 n i for all j, then

θ i = n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j = n i j = 1 n i ( 1 / n i ) α i j = n i ( 1 / n i ) j = 1 n i α i j = 1 .

And, in general, if j = 1 n i α i j ln ( f i j ) = ln ( n i ) then θ i = n i j = 1 n i f i j α i j = 1 .

Therefore, there are many combinations of f i j and α i j in which θ i = 1 and capital is conserved.

5. Conclusions

The CDR model gives us the basis for a unified theory for integrating the macro-economic CDR growth model into the micro-economic Cobb-Douglas production function. That is, a mapping from intangible aggregate macro-economic space into tangible micro-economic production spaces. In the particular cases studied in the paper, mapping CDR space into production spaces is homeomorphic and capital is preserved under certain prescribed combinations of the production units in the sense that the value measures of production sum to GDP. If the prescribed combinations are not present, then the aggregated values of the individual production units will not equate to GDP. Individual firms that construct production units operate independently of each other. So, the prescribed combinations will not exist except by some miracle. Therefore, there is no such thing as an aggregate production function.

We have seen from the CDR growth law (global time invariant CDR model) that the way in which capital is converted to gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity is a universal constant. After adjusting for country factors of productivity, said capital is converted in accordance with the physical and chemical laws of the natural sciences. Like capital, the coefficients of democracy, rule of law and their interaction are global time invariant. Economic catalysis by democracy and rule of law always function the same way across the world. What makes a country more productive is its ability to attract more capital. Future research could investigate additional configurations of production functions beyond the cases presented in this paper.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Paul Beaumont for comments and good discussions but take full responsibility for any errors and omissions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

Cite this paper

Ridley, D. and Ngnepieba, P. (2018) Conservation of Capital: Homeomorphic Mapping from Intangible Aggregate Macro-Economic CDR Space into Tangible Micro-Economic Production Spaces. Theoretical Economics Letters, 8, 2103-2115. https://doi.org/10.4236/tel.2018.811138

References

  1. 1. Schumpeter, J.A. (1911) Theory of Economic Development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

  2. 2. Schumpeter, J.A. (1928) The Entrepreneur. In: Becker, M., Knudsen, T. and Swedberg, R., Eds., The Entrepreneur: Classic Texts by J. Schumpeter, California: Stanford University Press, Stanford, 227-260.

  3. 3. Schumpeter, J.A. (1954) A History of Economic Analysis. Allen & Unwin, London.

  4. 4. Solow, R.M. (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65-94. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513

  5. 5. Solow, R.M. (1957) Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 312-320. https://doi.org/10.2307/1926047

  6. 6. Cobb, C.W. and Douglas, P.H. (1928) A Theory of Production. American Economic Review. Vol. 18, Supplement, Papers and Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, March 1928, 139-165.

  7. 7. Cohen, A.J. and Harcourt, G.C. (2003) Retrospectives: Whatever Happened to the Cambridge Capital Theory Controversies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 199-214. https://doi.org/10.1257/089533003321165010

  8. 8. Houthakker, H.S. (1955) The Pareto Distribution and the Cobb-Douglas Production Function in Activity Analysis. The Review of Economic Studies, 23, 27-31. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296148

  9. 9. Leontief, W. (1906-1999) Leontief Production Function. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Leontief_production_function

  10. 10. Ridley, A.D. (2016) The Entrepreneurial Community. Journal of Management and Engineering Integration, 9, 41-51.

  11. 11. Ridley, A.D. (2017) Wealth Is All in the Mind. International Journal of Social Science & Economic Research, 2, 3369-3379. http://ijsser.org/uploads/ijsser_02__208.pdf

  12. 12. Ridley, A.D. (2017) Division of Human Capital Creates Surplus Wealth. Bulletin of Political Economy, 11, 1-20. http://www.serialsjournals.com/serialjournalmanager/pdf/1520053852.pdf

  13. 13. Ridley, A.D. (2017) Micro Intrapreneurship. International Journal of Social Science & Economic Research, 2, 4729-4743. http://ijsser.org/uploads/ijsser_02__299.pdf

  14. 14. Ridley, A.D., Davis, B. and Korovyakovskaya, I. (2017) Entrepreneurial Mindset and the University Curriculum. Journal of Higher Education Theory and Practice, 17, 79-100.

  15. 15. Ridley, A.D. and Khan, A. (2018) Decoupling Entrepreneurship Capital from Capital Stock. Bulletin of Political Economy, 11.

  16. 16. Berzelius, J.J. (1779-1848). https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/J%C3%B6ns_Jacob_Berzelius

  17. 17. Weisstein, E.W. (2018) Homeomorphism. From Math World—A Wolfram Web Resource. http://mathworld.wolfram.com/Homeomorphism.html

  18. 18. Goel, R.K., Mazhar, U. and Nelson, M.A. (2016) Corruption across Government Occupations: Cross-National Survey Evidence. Journal of International Development, 28, 1220-1234. https://doi.org/10.1002/jid.3040

  19. 19. Czap, H.J. and Nur-tegin, K.D. (2012) Government Positions for Sale—A Model of Grand Corruption. Business and Politics, 14, 1-25. https://doi.org/10.1515/1469-3569.1414

  20. 20. Couttenier, M. and Toubal, F. (2017) Corruption for Sales. Journal of Comparative Economics, 45, 56-66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2016.11.008

  21. 21. López, W., Bocarejo, M.A.R., Peralta, D.R., Marín, C.P. and Mullet, E. (2017) Mapping Colombian Citizens’ Views Regarding Ordinary Corruption: Threat, Bribery, and the Illicit Sharing of Confidential Information. Social Indicators Research, 133, 259-273. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1366-6

  22. 22. Auty, R. (1993) Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The Resource Curse Thesis. Routledge, London.

  23. 23. Frankel, J.A. (2012) The Natural Resource Curse: A Survey of Diagnoses and Some Prescriptions. HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series RWP12-014, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge.

  24. 24. Norman, C. (2009) Rule of Law and the Resource Curse: Abundance versus Intensity. Environmental Resource Economics, 43, 183-207. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-008-9231-y

  25. 25. Sachs, J. and Warner, A.M. (2001) Natural Resources and Economic Development: The Curse of Natural Resources. European Economic Review, 45, 827-838. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00125-8

  26. 26. Ross, M. (2001) Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World Politics, 53, 326-361. https://doi.org/10.1353/wp.2001.0011

  27. 27. Sala-i-Martin, X. and Subramanian, A. (2003) Addressing the Natural Resource Curse: An Illustration from Nigeria. NBER Working Paper No. 9804. https://doi.org/10.3386/w9804

  28. 28. Humphreys, M. (2005) Natural Resources, Conflict and Conflict Resolution. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49, 508-537. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002705277545

  29. 29. Van der Ploeg, F. (2011) Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing? Journal of Economic Literature, 49, 366-420. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.49.2.366 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/jel.49.2.366

  30. 30. Wadho, W.A. (2014) Education, Rent Seeking and the Curse of Natural Resources. Economics & Politics, 26, 128-156. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecpo.12029

  31. 31. Ricardo, D. (1817) On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. J. M. Dent & Sons, Dover.

  32. 32. Ricardo, D. (1821) The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Dent, London.

  33. 33. Smith, A. (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Tantor. https://doi.org/10.1093/oseo/instance.00043218

Appendix

For convenience, the following appendix is reconstructed here from prior CDR publications.

1) The Global Time Invariant CDR model

Figure 1. Year 2014 G vs CDR Index for 79 countries (line). Bubble size (21 countries) is the square root of population. This model was re-estimated for years 1995 to 2016 with similar results. For additional comments on the countries listed see Ridley (2017a, 2017b).

2) Standardized g model

The ordinary least squares g model is specified as follows:

g = β 0 + β C C + β D D + β R R + β C D R C D R + β N N + ε

where, the intercept β 0 and the coefficients β C , β D , β R , β C D R , β N are all dimensionless, ε is a random, normally distributed error with a mean of zero and constant standard deviation, and where all model variables are standardized as follows:

g = G lowest G highest G lowest G

G = per capita real gross domestic product per capita (PPP)

C ( Capitalism ) = per capita capitalization lowestper capita capitalization highestper capita capitalization lowestper capita capitalization

D ( Democracy ) = lowest democracy rank democracy rank lowest democracy rank highest democracy rank

R ( Rule of law ) = lowest corruption rank corruption rank lowest corruption rank highest corruption rank

N ( Natural resources ) = per capita total natural resource rents lowest per capita total natural resource rents highest per capita total natural resource rents lowest per capita total natural resource rents

These transformations standardize the variables and ensures upper and lower bounds on 0 g , C , D , R , C D R , N 1 . Democracy and corruption are rank ordered, where the highest = 1 and the lowest = the number of countries. G is measured in $/capita/year.

Data for these standardized variables are listed in a supplementary spreadsheet.

Click here to download supplementary source data.

Data sources

G (PPP, constant international$ for 2014, reported by the IMF) http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm

Population http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.POP.TOTL

Capitalization (US$ mundi) http://www.indexmundi.com/facts/indicators/CM.MKT.LCAP.CD/rankings

Democracy rank http://democracyranking.org/wordpress/rank/democracy-ranking-2014/

Corruption rank https://www.transparency.org/research/cpi/

Total natural resources (% of G) http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.TOTL.RT.ZS

Democracy rank & corruption rank for Bermuda was set to that for United Kingdom as the governing country.

Democracy rank & corruption rank for Hong Kong was set to that for United Kingdom as the recent & last governing country.

Barbados (high CDR) and Equatorial Guinea (high G) are too small for attention by the reporting agencies.

g ^ = 1.53C + 0.14D + 0.23R − 1.21C∙D∙R + 0.38N

t = (6.60) (1.69) (2.60) (4.40) (5.59), F ratio = 81.

Partial correlations (contributions to R a d j 2 ):

59% 5% 10% 3% 6% R a d j 2 = 83 % .

83% Fratio=81

G ^ = g ^ (highest G-lowest G) + lowest G.

Highest G = 83,066. Lowest G = 1112.

The CDR index = 1.53C + 0.14D + 0.23R −1.21C∙D∙R comprises positive C, D and R effects and a negative component due to friction from democracy that reduces G from what it might otherwise be if there were perfect agreement amongst decision contributors. The contribution from N is negligible and can be dropped from the model since it is not a decision variable that is under the control of government.

The year 2014 CDR model (Figure 1) was re-estimated using samples from 2016 to 2016, 2015 to 2016, 2014 to 2016, 2013 to 2016, …, 1995 to 2016 (Figure 2). The β D , β R and β N parameter estimates from the CDR model are approximately constant for 22 years. They converge in the forward direction of time. The β C and β C D R estimates are approximately constant for the most recent 9 years. Prior to 2008, capitalization data were not available for all countries. So capitalization was held constant. Constancy and convergence of the parameter estimates demonstrates model stability and consistency. Even if there is some bias, the model yields useful stable predictions. Some two hundred and forty years after Smith [33] announced an inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, the cause is found to be capitalism, democracy and rule of law, and the CDR model places economics on a sound scientific footing.

Figure 2. CDR model parameters were re-estimated for years 1995 to 2016 with similar results.