Journal of Mathematical Finance
Vol.2 No.1(2012), Article ID:17601,6 pages DOI:10.4236/jmf.2012.21011

From Normal vs Skew-Normal Portfolios: FSD and SSD Rules

Francesco Blasi*, Sergio Scarlatti

School of Economics, University of Rome Tor Vergata, Rome, Italy

Email: sergio.scarlatti@uniroma2.it

Received September 26, 2011; revised November 16, 2011; accepted November 25, 2011

Keywords: Normal Distribution; Skew-Normal Distribution; Mixture Distributions; Stochastic Ordering; Stochastic Dominance; Portfolio Selection; Derivatives; Straddles

ABSTRACT

In this paper we study stochastic dominance rules of first and second order for univariate skew-normal random variables, the analysis being relevant in connection with the problem of portfolio choice in stock markets showing departure from the classical assumption of normality on returns. Besides that, our analysis is also relevant for markets where stocks returns are normally distributed: if standard derivatives are tradable and straddles, characterized by V-shaped pay-outs, are implementable at specific strike prices, then, portfolios including them, can exhibit exact skew-normality in their returns. We provide a set of simple conditions on the statistical parameters of the distributions which imply FSD and SSD and discuss some application of our criteria.

1. Introduction

Ranking portfolio return distributions is one of the key procedures which can be used by quantitative analysts to provide support to the decisional processes of portfolio managers. In this paper we discuss ranking criteria for skew-normal distributions based on stochastic dominance rules of first and second order; we refer the reader to Levy ([1]) for a detailed exposition of these concepts and many related results.

The economical motivation underpinning second order stochastic dominance (SSD) is particularly appealing: a representative investor with increasing and concave utility function will always prefer a portfolio to a portfolio if the the returns of stochastically dominate at the second order the returns of. SSD encapsulates therefore the concept of risk-aversion. Investments theorists and practitioners have developed along the times several methods to compare risky investments prospects or portfolios of assets and choose among the feasible ones in some optimal way: the review paper Brandt ([2]) and the book Sharpe et al. ([3]) discuss many of these methodologies. Probably the Markowitz’s mean-variance framework, Markowitz ([4]), remains the most famous approach, even if it is has well documented intrinsic limitations. There have been various attempts to overcome some of these limitations: by taking into account higher distributional moments as in Athayde et al. ([5]), by investigating bayesian versions of the Markowitz’s idea as in Pastor ([6]) and Polson ([7]), or by proposing alternative or more general risk measures as in Konno and Yamazaki ([8]), Markowitz et al. ([9]) and Feiri et al. ([10]). A very original and influential contribution to the asset allocation problem has been given by Black and Litterman in Black and Litterman ([11]): there the authors nicely incorporate in their framework subjective beliefs or “views” on expected future returns of assets (see Meucci ([12]) for a survey and extensions). Skewnormally distributed returns, which we handle in this paper, have been already considered in portfolio theory by Adcock and Shutes ([13]) and Harvey et al. ([14]), furthermore Adcock ([15]) and Bacmann and Massi-Benedetti ([16]) contain interesting applications to hedge funds portfolios. However, to our best knowledge, the stochastic dominance approach for comparing skewnormally distributed returns is considered here for the first time. Notice that stochastic dominance rules aim to compare the whole distribution and not just a limited number of its moments. Finally we refer to Post ([17]) for applications of stochastic dominance rules to empirical data. This paper is organized as follows. In the next section we consider markets with skew-normal returns and portfolios on these markets; in Section 3 we show that even in markets with normal returns in the basic securities there can be portfolios exhibiting skewnormality in their returns if on the same market derivatives based strategies with V-shaped payouts can be implemented. In Section 4 we prove our stochastic dominance criteria and illustrate some possible applications.

2. Portfolios in Skew-Normal Markets

Following Azzalini ([18]) let us recall that a random vector is said to follow the skew-normal distribution with location parameter, scale matrix and shape parameter if its density has the form:

(1)

where is the diagonal matrix

, for,

is the density of a -random vector and is the cumulative distribution function of a univariate standard normal. In this case we write. In particular, in the univariate case, has the skew-normal distribution of parameters and if for all

where. In this case we write

. Clearly for we have

. For the distribution is skewed and indeed its mean, variance and skewness can be easily computed. They are respectively given by:

with.

We refer the reader to Arellano and Azzalini ([19]) and Genton ([20]) for further properties and many interesting applications.

Let us now consider a market with basic risky assets whose future returns, at time, are described by a random vector such that:

(2)

An investor, the decision maker, is facing with the problem of allocating her initial capital on the market by choosing a portfolio, with and holding it unchanged up to time. The portfolio return is given by the random variable with:

(3)

and parameters, , and

(4)

where and, see Azzalini ([18]). Henceforth it is clear that in order to compare the returns of two different portfolios and on this market we must have at our disposal criteria which allow us to compare two univariate skew-normal random variables. In Section 4 we prove simple criteria based on stochastic dominance, Levy ([1]). Although we only make use of standard techniques, to our best knowledge these results have never been discussed in the classical literature on the subject. An investor can use them to discard a portfolio or a family of portfolios whose returns are stochastically dominated by the return of another portfolio.

3. Portfolios Including Derivative Securities in Normal Markets

In this section we briefly show how the skew-normal return distributions can naturally appear even in markets with normal returns in the primary risky assets, if in the same markets are traded derivative securities which incorporate non-linear pay-offs. More specifically consider markets for which the shape parameters of the basic risky assets are all zero (), that is

(5)

and suppose that a straddle on one of the assets is available at a cost and strike price. To simplify the exposition we fix and denote by and the market basic risky securities; therefore their returns over the interval will follow the law:

(6)

with and. Let be their present spot prices, a straddle is written on the first asset and will pay to the holder, denoting the asset price at maturity date. Consider an investor who wishes to allocate percentages of her capital both on the straddle and on shares of asset, while investing the remaining part on a risk-free bond. It turns out that for a strike value equal to the portfolios returns will display skew-normality. This condition on appears to be very stringent, however in practice we could have with returns distribution close to skew-normality. Notice that the case corresponds to a straddle traded “at the money” (this particular case, and with, has been discussed by Blasi ([21])). Indeed denoting by the percentage of initial capital invested on the straddle on asset, by the percentage of initial capital invested on asset, the return of the portfolio, at time will be

(7)

where, , is the bond yield and standardized assets returns have been denoted by. We notice that a decomposition analogous to (7) continues to hold also for the multi-asset case (), that is for portfolios investing on a straddle on one of the assets, on shares of the remaining risky assets and on the risky-free asset. The following result is a straightforward generalization of a result by Henze ([22]) and can be proven by elementary methods:

Proposition 3.1 Let be correlated random variables. Let denote the correlation coefficient, , and and real numbers. Then the random variable

is a mixture of two skew-normally distributed random variables. Specifically, denoting by the probability density of, it holds:

where

with and.

In particular for we have:

For example it is readily seen that for the above result implies:

(8)

with parameters:

(9)

(10)

(11)

We remark that given and the assets volatilities the shape parameter depends only on the ratio of the chosen allocation percentages and vanishes for. Shorting the straddle or the second asset produces portfolios with negative shape parameter in the returns distribution and hence with negative skewness. On the other hand positive skewness increases unboundedly as the percentage approaches zero. Furthermore, for the above portfolios returns distributions scale and shape parameters satisfy the relation , which implies that scale changes with shape. In the case the returns will be described, accordingly to the previous proposition, by a mixture of two skew-normal distributions, the identification of and being straightforward. We remark that while on one hand finite mixture of normaldistributions have been already considered in the financial literature as possible flexible tool for modelling assets returns in portfolio selection problems (Buckley et al. ([23])), on the other hand finite mixture of skewnormal distributions up to now have received attention mainly in applied statistical settings, see for instance Lee et al. ([24]), but not in connection with financial applications.

An immediate consequence of the example discussed above is the fact that even in a normal market an investor can face the problem of comparing portfolios having returns which are skew-normally distributed. Once again the decision maker needs criteria which can help her allocation choice process by discarding portfolios which have dominated returns. In the next section we shall provide some simple, yet rigorous, stochastic dominance criteria.

4. Stochastic Dominance Results

We start recalling some basic definitions: given two realvalued random variables and we say that stochastically dominates at first order (FSD), and we shortly write if

(12)

for all; we say that stochastically dominates at second order (SSD), and we shortly write if

(13)

for all. More generally, a random variable stochastically dominates another random variable at the order n-th if

for all values. If the previous inequalities hold strictly we say that we have strict dominance. Obviously (n − 1)-th order dominance implies n-th order dominance.

The classical stochastic ordering results for univariate normal random variables and are the following (ref. Levy (2005)):

1) If and then;

2) If and then

In particular we have strict dominance for and (or and).

To provide a generalization of these results to the skewnormal case we need the following:

Theorem 4.1:

1) Let and

. Suppose, then

.

2) Let and . Suppose then

.

3) Let and. Suppose and, then.

4) Let and . Suppose and

, then.

Proof.

1) Let and denote by the corresponding distribution function. For each fixed and and arbitrary we consider the function. We have:

where we have used

and. Therefore is decreasing and for all.

2) For each fixed and and arbitrary we consider the function. We have:

by integrating by parts the first of the two integrals.

Therefore is decreasing and for all.

3) For each fixed and and arbitrary we consider the function. We have:

and by integrating by parts the last integral

which is non negative for all.

Henceforth is increasing,

for all, and we get the result.

4) Set then and the second assumption on the parameters is equivalent to

for. For each fixed and

and arbitrary we consider the function , where

. We have:

Now, hence:

which is non negative. Henceforth is increasing for all.

Remark: The argument by which the result (3) has been obtained fails for. In such a case is given by the difference of two positive quantities. The difference is positive for since. On the contrary for values of much larger than the difference is negative since the first quantity becomes much smaller than the second one. Therefore for positive the sign of is going to depend on the values of the variable.

Corollary 4.2:

1) Let and

. Suppose andthen.

2) Let and

. Suppose, and

, then.

3) Let and

. Suppose, and

, then.

Proof.

1) Let, then by lemma 2.1 (i) and (2) we have:

2) Let andthen by lemma 2.1 (1), (2) and (3) we have:

3) Let, then by lemma 2.1 (2)

and (4) we have:

Remark: a) The condition appearing in Corollary 4.2 (3) can be better understood by noticing that is equivalent to. Therefore the result can be restated in the following form: If, and then.

b) Let and

with. Being we have and from Corollary 4.2 (3) it follows. Notice that

.

Henceforth, a larger positive skewness parameter in a financial position gives rise to an improvement over a previous position, from a stochastic dominance viewpoint, if it is accompanied by a variance reduction which leaves unchanged the skewness of the position.

c) It is well known that if and only if for all non decreasing and concave functions. Therefore, by choosing, conditions (2) of Corollary 4.2 imply.

d) Consider the two-dimensional risky market discussed in Section 2 and the parametrized family of portfolios which invest on the straddle on asset, on shares of asset, putting all the remaining wealth on a riskfree bond. Assume and. Consider two portfolios and and the corresponding returns and. Suppose 1), 2)

, and 3)

, then from (2) we get

.

In addition from (3) we obtain. Finally from (1) we have and therefore Then by Corollary 4.2 (2) we get.

5. Acknowledgements

The authors thank the anonymous referee for useful suggestions which led to improvements in the presentation of the results. The second named author thanks Prof. A. Ramponi for advices and Centro V. Volterra for financial support.

REFERENCES

  1. H. Levy, “Stochastic Dominance,” Springer-Verlag, New York, 2005.
  2. M. W. Brandt, “Portfolio Choice Problems,” In Y. AitSahalia and L. P. Hansen, Eds., Handbook of Financial Econometrics, forthcoming.
  3. W. Sharpe, G. J. Alexander and G. W. Bailey, “Investments,” Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, 1998.
  4. H. Markowitz, “Portfolio Selection,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1, 1952, pp. 77-91. doi:10.2307/2975974
  5. G. M. de Athayde and R. G. Flores, Jr., “Finding a Maximum Skewness Portfolio: A General Solution to Three Moments Portfolio Choice,” Journal of Economical Dynamics and Control, Vol. 28, No. 7, 2004, pp. 1335-1352. doi:10.1016/S0165-1889(02)00084-2
  6. L. Pastor, “Portfolio Selection and Asset Pricing Models,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 55, No. 1, 2000, pp. 179- 223. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00204
  7. N. G. Polson, “Bayesian Portfolio Selection: An Empirical Analysis of the S & P 500 Index 1970-1996,” Journal of Business Economical Statistics, Vol. 18, No. 2, 2000, pp. 164-173. doi:10.2307/1392554
  8. H. Konno and H. Yamazaki, “Mean-Absolute Deviation Portfolio Optimization Model and Its Applications to Tokyo Stock Market,” Management Science, Vol. 37, No. 5, 1991, pp. 519-531. doi:10.1287/mnsc.37.5.519
  9. H. Markowitz, P. Todd, G. Xu and Y. Yamane, “Computation of Semivariance Efficient Sets by the Critical Line Algorithm,” Annals of Operations Research, Vol. 45, No. 1, 1993, pp. 307-317. doi:10.1007/BF02282055
  10. F. J. Feiring, W. Wong, M. Poon and Y. C. Chan, “Portfolio Selection in Downside Risk Optimization Approach: Application to the Hong-Kong Stock Market,” International Journal of Systems Science, Vol. 25, No. 1-3, 1994, pp. 1921-1929. doi:10.1080/00207729408949322
  11. F. Black and R. Litterman, “Asset Allocation: Combining Investor Views with Market Equilibrium,” The Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 1, No. 2, 1991, pp. 7-18. doi:10.3905/jfi.1991.408013
  12. A. Meucci, “The Black-Litterman Approach: Original Model and Extensions,” The Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance, Wiley, New York, 2010.
  13. C. J. Adcock and K. Shutes, “Portfolio Selection Based on the Multivariate Skewed Normal Distribution,” In: A. Skulimowski, Ed., Financial Modelling, Progress & Business Publishers, Krakow, 2001
  14. C. Harvey, J. Liechty, M. Liechty and P. Muller, “Portfolio Selection with Higher Moments,” Quantitative Finance, Vol. 10, No. 5, 2010, pp. 469-485. doi:10.1080/14697681003756877
  15. C. J. Adcock, “Exploiting Skewness to Built an Optimal Hedge Fund with a Currency Overlay,” European Journal of Finance, Vol. 11, No. 5, 2005, pp. 445-462. doi:10.1080/13518470500039527
  16. J. F. Bacmann and S. Massi-Benedetti, “Optimal Bayesian Portfolios of Hedge Funds,” International Journal of Risk Assessment and Management, Vol. 11, No. 12, 2009, pp. 39-57. doi:10.1504/IJRAM.2009.022196
  17. T. Post, “Empirical Tests for Stochastic Dominance Efficiency,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 58, No. 5, 2003, pp. 1905-1931. doi:10.1111/1540-6261.00592
  18. A. Azzalini, “The Multivariate Skew-Normal Distribution and Related Multi-Variate Families (with Discussion),” Scandinavian Journal of Statistics, Vol. 32, 2005, pp. 159- 188. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9469.2005.00426.x
  19. R. B. Arellano and A. Azzalini, “The Centered Parametrization for the Multivariate Skew-Normal Distribution,” Journal of Multivalent Analysis, Vol. 99, 2008, pp. 1362- 1382. doi:10.1016/j.jmva.2008.01.020
  20. M. G. Genton, “Skew-Elliptical Distributions and Their Applications: A Journey beyond Normality,” Chapman & Hall/CRC, Boca Raton, 2004. doi:10.1201/9780203492000
  21. F. S. Blasi, “Black-Litterman Model in a Skew-Normal Market,” Statistical Computation and Complex Systems 2009, Milan, 14-16 September 2009.
  22. N. Henze, “A Probabilistic Representation of the ‘SkewNormal’ Distribution,” Scandinavion Journal of Statistics, Vol. 13, 1986, pp. 271-275.
  23. I. Buckley, D. Saunders and L. Seco, “Portfolio Optimization When Asset Returns Have the Gaussian Mixture Distribution,” European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 185, No. 3, 2008, pp. 1434-1461. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2005.03.080
  24. T. I. Lin, J. C. Lee and S. Y. Yen, “Finite Mixture Modelling Using the Skew-Normal Distribution,” Statistica Sinica, Vol. 17, No. 3, 2007, pp. 909-927.

NOTES

*GDF-SUEZ Trading [The present paper expresses only the authors own views and in absolute no way represents opinions of GDF-SUEZ Trading or its Management Board].