1. Introduction
It is a well-known fact that variable transformations are valuable in considering the effect of tax and transfer policies on income inequality. The transformation is usually assumed to be positive, monotone increasing and continuous. Under the assumption that the theorems should hold for all income distributions, conditions given earlier are both necessary and sufficient [1,2]. In this study, we reconsider the effect of variable transformations on the redistribution of income. Different versions of the conditions are compared [1,3-5]. One main result is that continuity is a necessary condition if one assumes that income inequality should remain or be reduced. In addition, in our earlier studies of classes of tax policies, the results were based on the assumption that the transformations were differentiable and satisfies a derivative condition [6,7].
2. Basic Properties of Income Transformations
Consider income X with the distribution function
, the mean
, and the Lorenz curve
. We assume that X is defined for
and that
is continuous.
A fundamental theorem concerning the effect of income transformations on Lorenz curves and Lorenz dominance was given by Fellman [3] and Jakobsson [1] and later by Kakwani [4]. We have.
Theorem 1. [1,3,4]. Let X be an arbitrary non-negative, random variable with the distribution
, mean
, and Lorenz curve
. Let
be nonnegative, continuous and monotone-increasing and let
exist. Then the Lorenz curve
of
exists and the following results hold 1) 
if
is monotone decreasing;
2) 
if
is constant and;
3) 
if
is monotone increasing.
Following Fellman [2], we obtain in 1) a sufficient condition that the transformation
generates a new income distribution which Lorenz dominates the initial one. The analysis should be based on the difference
(1)
where
; that is,
[2]. Furthermore,
. In order to obtain Lorenz dominance, the difference
in Equation (1) must start from zero, attain positive values and then decrease back to zero. Consequently, the difference
(2)
must start from positive (non-negative) values and then change its sign and become negative. If
is exceptionally increasing within the interval
, then a variable X with a distribution
defined in the interval
exists such that 3) holds and
. Consequently, the condition that
is decreasing is necessary if the rule holds for all income distributions
[1,2]. Analogously, if the other results in Theorem 1 hold for every income distribution, the conditions in 2) and 3) are also necessary.
Hence, the continuity of
is a necessary condition if we demand that the transformed variable should Lorenz dominate the initial variable for every distribution. From this it follows that if the condition in Theorem 1 1) has to be necessary, it implies continuity and hence an explicit statement of continuity can be dropped. Considering the condition in 2), we observe that
and
consequently is continuous.
However, in case 3) discontinuities do not jeopardize the monotone increasing property of the quotient
and the result in Theorem 1 3) holds even if the function is discontinuous. Therefore, Fellman [2] dropped the explicit continuity assumption in this case as well.
Summing up, for arbitrary distributions,
, the conditions 1), 2), and 3) in Theorem 1 are both necessary and sufficient for the dominance relations and an additional assumption about the continuity of the transformation
can be dropped. We obtain the more general theorem [2].
Theorem 2. Let X be an arbitrary non-negative, random variable with the distribution
, mean
and Lorenz curve
, let
be a non-negative, monotone increasing function and let
and
exist. Then the Lorenz curve
of Y exists and the following results hold:
1) 
if and only if
is monotone-decreasing 2) 
if and only if
is constant 3) 
if and only if
is monotone-increasing.
Remark. It follows from the discussion above that the transformation
can be discontinuous only in case 3).
Hemming and Keen [5] gave an alternative condition for Lorenz dominance. Their condition, with our notations, is that for a given distribution
,
crosses the
level once from above. Consequently,
in (2) starts from positive valueschanges its sign once and ends up with negative values. Hence, their condition is equivalent to our condition.
Furthermore, if we assume that
is monotonedecreasing (non-increasing), then
satisfies the condition “crossing once from above for every distribution
”. Hence, both conditions, the HemmingKeen condition and ours, are also equivalent as necessary conditions. Recently, Fellman [8] obtained limits for the transformed Lorenz curves. These limits are related to the results given by Hemming and Keen.
3. Properties of Tax Policies
If we apply the results above to tax policies, the transformed variable
is the income after the taxation (cf., e.g., [6,7,9,10]). In order to obtain a realistic class of policies, Fellman [6,7] assumed continuous transformations and included the additional restriction
. This condition indicates that the tax paid is an increasing function of the income x. In order to generalize the results and allow that the function
is not uniformly differentiable everywhere, we replace the derivative restriction in this study by the more general condition
. According to this restriction, the tax is an increasing function of the income x. In fact, the tax is
and the increment in the tax is
and a positive increment
yields the restriction
. If
holds, it follows that
(3)
but the condition
is more general and does not imply uniform differentiability. Both restrictions imply that the transformation
is continuous. We intend to show that the assumption
is sufficient for the whole theory.
Now, the class of tax policies is U:
(4)
We consider the extreme policies
(5)
and
(6)
It is apparent that while function (5) is not differentiable at point
and (6) at point
, the condition
holds for all x. The Lorenz curve corresponding to (5) is
(7)
where
and the Lorenz curve corresponding to (6) is
(8)
where
([6]).
Policy (5) is optimal, that is, it Lorenz dominates all the policies in class U, and policy (6) is Lorenz dominated by all policies in U [6,7].
In the following, we show how the main result in [7] can be obtained when we replace the restriction
by the more general restriction
. The function
may be piecewise differentiable like transformations (5) and (6). We consider post-tax income distributions with the mean
. Without the restriction
, the necessary and sufficient condition that a given Lorenz curve
of the distribution
corresponds to a member of class U is that the initial distribution
stochastically dominates
. The inclusion of the restriction
results in the stochastic dominance being only necessary; that is, the transformed distribution
must satisfy additional conditions.
Assume a given differentiable Lorenz curve
with a continuous derivative. These conditions can be assumed because the corresponding transformation
has to continuously satisfy the condition
. Starting from
, the connection between
and the post-tax distribution
with the mean
is that
, where
is the inverse function of
. The corresponding transformation is 
The condition
can be written as
(9)
where
and 
On the other hand, we can write
(10)
and define
and 
.
If we assume that
is piecewise differentiable, then
and
are piecewise differentiable.
If we assume that the density functions
and
exist, we obtain
(11)
where
and
(12)
where
and
.
Consequently,
and 
From
and from the condition
it follows that
(13)
and, consequently,
. If we let
, then
and
and we obtain
for all p. This condition can also be written as
or
(14)
when
. We can reverse the steps from (14) to (9) and all the results in Fellman [7] still hold, but the proof had to be slightly modified.
4. Conclusions
In this study we reconsidered the effect of variable transformations on the redistribution of income. The aim was to generalise the conditions considered in earlier papers. We were particularly interested in whether we could drop the assumption of differentiability of the transformations when tax policies are considered. The main result is that with a slight modification of the proof the additional condition
is obtained.
We have also seen that if we demand sufficient and necessary conditions, theorems obtained earlier still hold and the continuity assumption can be included in the general conditions. The main result is that continuity is a necessary condition if one maintains that the income inequality should remain or be reduced.
The study of the class of tax policies indicated that the differentiability assumed earlier, can be dropped but, if one wants to retain the realism of the class, the transformations should still be continuous and satisfy the restriction
. The previous results in Fellman [6,7] still hold.
Empirical applications of the optimal policies of a class of transfer policies and the class of tax policies considered here have been discussed by Fellman et al. [9,10], where “optimal yardsticks” to gauge the effectiveness of given real tax and transfer policies in reducing inequality were developed.