Optimal Investment under Dual Risk Model and Markov Modulated Financial Market

Abstract

In this paper, the optimal investment problem for an agent with dual risk model is studied. The financial market is assumed to be a diffusion process with the coefficients modulated by an external process, which is specified by the solution to a kind of stochastic differential equation. The object of the agent is to maximize the expected utility from terminal wealth. Together with the regularity property of the value function, by dynamic programming principle, the value function of our control problem is turned to be the unique solution to the associated Hamilton-Jacob-Bellman (HJB for short) equation. When the utility is an exponential function with constant risk aversion, close form expressions for value function and optimal investment policy are obtained.

Share and Cite:

Xu, L. , Zhang, L. and Zhu, D. (2015) Optimal Investment under Dual Risk Model and Markov Modulated Financial Market. Journal of Mathematical Finance, 5, 157-171. doi: 10.4236/jmf.2015.52015.

1. Introduction

The classical surplus process of an insurer is given by

(1)

where x > 0 is the initial surplus, c is the positive constant premium income rate, Nt is Poisson process with parameter, which denotes the total number of claims up to time t. Denote the time of arrival of the ith claim by Ti and the size of the ith claim by Yi. More details about the surplus process can be found in Asmussen and Albrecher [1] , Rolski et al. [2] . As pointed out by Albrecher et al. [3] , its dual process may also be relevant for companies whose inherent business involves a constant flow of expenses while revenues arrive occasionally due to some contingent events (e.g. discoveries, sales). For instance, pharmaceutical or petroleum companies are prime examples of companies for which it is reasonable to model their surplus process as

(2)

The past decade has witnessed an increasing attention on the research of dual risk model. For example, see Albrecher et al. [3] for optimal dividend problem, see Cheung and Drekic [4] for dividend approximation and dual risk model with perturbation, see Yao et al. [5] for optimal dividend and equity issuance, see Zhu and Yang [6] for ruin probability under a Markov modulated dual risk model.

As we all know, investment is an important element in the financial agent for which can bring them potential profit. Thus, optimal investment for insurers has drawn great attentions in recent years, for example, see the works of Bai and Guo [7] , Browne [8] , Fleming and Hernández [9] , Hipp and Plum [10] , Li et al. [11] , Zhang and Siu et al. [12] . However, to our best knowledge, there are few papers concentrate on the optimal investment of agent with dual risk process. This is the main contributions of this paper.

Usually, the coefficients of the dynamics of the financial market are assumed to be constant. However, in reality, the returns from the risky assets might not be constants. So, it would be of practical relevance and importance to consider asset pricing models with non-constant coefficients, which can incorporate the feature of non- stationary returns. Among all kinds of stochastic coefficients models, Markov-modulated risky model has been recognized recently as an important feature to asset price models. There is much literature documenting such models in assets returns, such as French et al. [13] . Meanwhile, since Markov-modulated risky model contains several very important stochastic volatility models, thus can be seen as an explanation of many well-known empirical findings, such as the volatility smile, the volatility clustering, and the heavy-tailed nature of return distributions (c.f. Fleming and Hernández [9] , Pham [14] , Zariphopoulou [15] [16] , and references therein). In this paper, the optimal investment problem of an agent with dual risk process under the Markov modulated financial market is studied. By dynamic programming principle, we obtained the HJB equations satisfied by the value function and finished the corresponding verification theorem. A solid example is presented to illustrate how to solve the HJB equation when the claims are exponential distribution. This rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, the model and problem are introduced. The HJB equation associated with our control problem and the verification theorem for optimal control are investigated in Section 3. In Section 4, we focus on the exponential utility function and closed form expression for optimal investment is obtained. In Section 5, we listed the highlights of this paper and conclusions from the results.

2. Formulation of the Problem

Let be a complete probability space which carries all random variables to appear in this paper. To proceed our discussion, we introduce the following variables and notations. Let and are two standard Brownian motions, which describe the perturbations of the insurer and the financial market and is the augmented filtration generated by aforementioned stochastic process, i.e.

and satisfying the usual conditions. For simplicity, , , and are assumed to be mutually independent.

Assume that there are two kinds of asset available for investors, one risky asset and one risk free asset. The risky asset is assumed to be

(2.1)

where, are the stochastic investment return rate and volatility of the risky market respectively. The dynamic of the external factor is specified by the solution to the following stochastic differential equation (SDE for short)

(2.2)

where, and. are correlated Brownian motions with the correlation coefficient. Model (2.2) covers many Markov modulated risk models, such as the Heston model and a special CIR model. Our model also includes a risk-free asset governed by

(2.3)

where is the interest rate function. We interpret the process Zt as the behavior of some economic factor that has an impact on the dynamics of the risky asset and the risk-free asset price. In this paper, we allow the company takes an investment strategy into account when making decisions. Then if Xt is the company’s wealth, and let Kt denote the amount invested into the risky asset at time t. The remained reserve is invested into the risk-free asset, then the wealth process of the insurer can be written as following equation. To clarify the impact of investment policy, we adopt as the wealth process of the insurer, then

(2.4)

where is the initial surplus of the insurer and c the positive real constant premium rate. Moreover, if at time the wealth of the insurer is x and the external factor is z. Then the wealth process satisfies

with the convention that.

Definition 1 We say that the strategy is admissible if it satisfies the following conditions

1) The strategies Kt has to be measurable and predictable with respect to the filtration;

2) There is a constant CK which may depend on the strategies K such that

We denote the set of admissible strategies as.

Suppose that the company is interested in maximizing the expected utility of wealth at time T. Without loss of generality, we can define the utility function to be a twice continuously differentiable function, with and, then our goal is the following value function:

(2.5)

We say that an admissible combined strategies is optimal if

Hypothesis 1 1) The functions, and are such that there is a strong solution for SDE (2.1), (2.2) for example the functions fulfil Lipschitz and linear growth conditions.

2) The function is continuous, positive and for all.

3. Properties of Value Function and the Verification Theorem

In this section we embed the problem of maximizing the expected utility from terminal wealth on a finite horizon in the framework of stochastic control theory by dynamic programming method. Then the HJB equation associated with the control problem (2.5) is given by

(3.1)

with terminal condition, where

The following verification theorem shows that under some proper conditions, a solution to previous HJB equation provides us the optimal investment policy.

Theorem 2 (The Verification Theorem) Suppose that there is a smooth solution to the HJB Equation (3.1) with terminal condition. Assume also that for each

(3.2)

(3.3)

(3.4)

Then for each

Suppose further that there exist two bounded measurable functions, such that

then defines a pair of optimal strategy and

Proof. Let, by Itô’s Lemma, it follows that for

(3.5)

where is the Poisson random measure on defined by

Compensate (3.5) by

we have

(3.6)

Assumptions (3.3) and (3.4) mean that

are martingales. Assumption (2.8) implies that

is a martingale. Then, by taking the expectation on both sides of (2.11) yields that

(3.7)

Note that f is a smooth solution to HJB equation (2.6), we have

That is to say for any,

(3.8)

Taking in (2.13), it follows that

(3.9)

The proof of the second part of this theorem follows in a similar manner. If we plug back into (2.12), for all we obtain

(3.10)

By taking the supremum over all in (2.15), we obtain the inequality

By considering (2.13) for all, we deduce that

Letting in the last equality, we have

Moreover, by recalling (2.14), it is easy to find that

This completes the proof.

Remark 1 Classical method of applying HJB equation for solving optimal control problems is pre-assume (or find) that there exist a smooth solution to the HJB equation, and then finish the argument by verification theorem. However, the HJB equations do not always admit classical solution, and thus the verification theorem invalid. In this case, viscosity solution will be introduced to cover the connections between the optimal control problem and the HJB equation. However, in next section, we exploit a closed representation of the solution to the HJB Equation (3.1) when the utility function is an exponential type. By this results, we further find the closed from optimal investment policy and the expressions of value function. As to very general utility function, it is difficult to find closed form solutions to HJB equation and we leave it as future research.

4. Existence of a Optimal Pair of Solutions under the Exponential Utility Function

In this section, we devote to the existence and uniqueness of the solution of the HJB Equation (3.1) when the preferences of the insurer are exponential, i.e., the utility function is governed by

(4.1)

In order to get a linear PDE, in the remainder of this paper we consider only the case where the correlation coefficient is equal to zero. Besides Hypothesis 1, we make the following assumptions.

Hypothesis 2 1) is constant;

2) g is uniformly Lipschitz and bounded;

3) bounded with a bounded first derivative;

Considering the form of the utility function, We speculate the following function as a solution to the HJB Equation (3.1)

(4.2)

where will be governed below by a solution to a Cauchy problem. From the definition of, we obtain

(4.3)

(4.4)

(4.5)

(4.6)

(4.7)

Plugging these partial derivatives of f into the HJB Equation (3.1), we obtain

(4.8)

For simplicity of presentation let us introduce the following notation

It is trivial to see that the supremum is achieved at

Indeed, by a measurable selection theorem, we may find a pair of bounded progressively measurable processes satisfied the supremum in (4.8). By substituting into (4.8), we obtain the following Cauchy problem:

(4.9)

The following theorem asserts the existence and uniqueness of aforementioned Cauchy equation (4.9).

Theorem 3 Assume that

(4.10)

Then the Cauchy problem given by (4.9) has a unique solution, which satisfies the following conditions:

(4.11)

(4.12)

where C1 and C2 are constants.

Proof. The theorem will be proved if we can show that the Cauchy problem given by (4.9) satisfies the conditions of the Theorem A.1. So we just need to check them.

・ Since is constant, naturally, it is Lipschitz continuous, Hölder continuous, and the operator is uniformly elliptic.

・ Considering Hypothesis 2, we know immediately that is bounded and uniformly Lipschitz continuous.

・ Now we show that

is bounded and uniformly Hölder continuous in compact subsets of.

In fact, by Hypothesis 2, it is clear that the first term of is bounded. The second term is bounded by. Note that for we have

Thus is bounded. Next we prove that is uniformly Hölder continuous in compact subsets of. Denote

Noting that is bounded with a bounded first derivative by, and Hypothesis 2, then it follows from Lemma A.1 that is uniformly Hölder continuous with exponent, i.e., for all

For the second term of, combining the mean value theorem and the Hypothesis 2 and Definition 1, we have that for all, such that

Then is uniformly Lipschitz in. Therefore is uniformly Hölder continuous in the compact set. For the third term of, first, a routine computation gives rise to the following derivatives

Then by the mean value theorem of bivariate functions, we know that there is such that

where and mean, for instance, ,. In the last line, we used. So we obtain

By (4.10), we obtain that is uniformly Lipschitz continuous in, and then is uniformly Hölder continuous in compact subsets of.

Since the Cauchy problem (4.9) is homogeneous with a constant terminal condition, then the right-hand side of (4.9) satisfies the property of linear growth and continuous. Finally, the conditions of Theorem A.1, it is easy to find that the Cauchy problem (4.9) has a unique solution which satisfies (4.11) and (4.12). The proof of the theorem is now complete.

The aim of the next theorem is to relate the value function V in the form (4.2) to the HJB Equation (3.1) in the form of the Cauchy problem (4.9).

Theorem 4 If (4.10) are satisfied, then the value function defined by (2.5) has the form:

where is the unique solution of the Cauchy problem (4.8), In addition, if

then the investment strategy is optimal, When, we get

and

Proof. We have already verified that

is a smooth solution of the HJB Equation (3.1). To prove that really copies the value function, we need to verify that Assumptions (3.2)-(3.4) of the Theorem 2 are satisfied by.

Firstly, we consider the case in which. Let be a pair of admissible strategies, then by (4.11) and the fact that Y is independent of and, we have

In the last line, we used for and. To get condition (3.2), it suffices to obtain an estimate of

We find that

In the last inequality, we used Hölder inequality (, where and). By considering Hypothesis 2.2 and Theorem A.2, we know that

where C is a positive constant. Moreover, by the Minkovski inequality

(, where), one will find that

(4.13)

i.e., Then it is enough to estimate Denote

One should note that

and

Recall that K is a pair of admissible strategy, by Hölder inequality, we have

Since is a martingale, it follows that

This indicates that, i.e., (3.2) holds for the case. In order to prove conditions (3.3) and (3.4), by (4.11) and (4.12) we have

and

Evidently, (3.3) and (3.4) are easily seen to hold with. For the case in which the interest rate, let By Itô’s formula it is easy to see that satisfies the following SDE

(4.14)

By for all in the Hypothesis 1, we obtain that

(4.15)

This case is dealt with the same arguments by suitable modification to the first part of the proof. First, we get

and

To accomplish the proof, it is sufficient to prove that

(4.16)

Note that

and the fact that from the first part of the proof, the proof is reduced to showing In fact, by applying (4.15) and with similar arguments to the first part of the proof we have

Similarly, since K is a pair of admissible strategy and is a martingale, we also have

This completes the proof.

5. Highlights and Summary

The main contributions of this paper include:

・ Both stochastic coefficients financial model and dual risk model are taken into account.

・ Rigorous proof of verification theorem for optimal policy is provided and closed form expressions for optimal policies and value function are derived.

・ A solid example is presented to illustrate how to solve the HJB equation.

As a result, we find that the optimal investment policy is a function of the state of the external Modulate Markov process. When there is no modulated process, the model considered in this paper is reduced to the optimal investment problem under the risky market with stationary coefficient and our results cover those existing results (see Bai and Guo [7] or Li et al. [11] ). One should note that when the coefficients are not sensitivity to the changes of the external Markov process, i.e. when the external Markov process changes, the coefficients of the risky market do not oscillate greatly, then our optimal investment policies seem to be very conservative because the optimal investment amount is near to a constant.

Acknowledgements

The authors are very grateful to anonymous referees’ detailed comments and suggestions, which makes this paper much better. Lin Xu would like to acknowledge the support of the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 11201006). Zhu Dongjin would like to acknowledge the support of Major Projects of Colleges and Universities in Anhui Province Natural Science Foundation (KJ2012ZD01).

Appendix. Parabolic Partial Differential Equations

To illuminate the expression of our research problem, now we introduce and summarize some important results on parabolic PDEs, which play a key role in the proof of Theorem 4.1 (existence and uniqueness theorem), and some terminology and definitions are introduced. We believe that this work will be useful in the development of this paper.

Definition 5 Let

1) We say that E is uniformly elliptic, if there is such that

for all and all

2) A function f on is called Hölder continuous in x with exponent, uniformly with respect to t in compact subsets of, if for each compact set there is a constant such that

3) f is said to be uniformly Hölder continuous in in compact subsets of if for each compact set there is a constant C such that

Theorem A.1 (Friedman, 1975). We consider the following Cauchy problem:

(A.1)

where L is given by

If the Cauchy problem (A.1) satisfies the following conditions:

1) The coefficients of L are uniformly elliptic;

2) The functions are bounded in and uniformly Lipschitz continuous in in compact subsets of;

3) The functions are Hölder continuous in x, uniformly with respect to in;

4) The function is bounded in and uniformly Hölder continuous in in compact subsets of;

5) The function is continuous in, uniformly Hölder continuous in x with respect to

) and;

6) The function is continuous in and with; then there is a unique solution u of the Cauchy problem (A.1) satisfying

and

Lemma A.1 Let f be a real positive bounded function with bounded derivative, then f is uniformly Hölder continuous with exponent, i.e.,

Proof. By the mean value theorem and using that is bounded,we have:

where K is a constant. By f is positive,we have

i.e.

The proof of this Lemma is now complete.

Theorem A.2 (Pham, 1998). Let be a stochastic processes defined by the following SDE:

with a standard Brownian motion Bs. We assume that for some, the coefficients satisfy:

(A.2)

for all. Let T > 0 and. Then, there is such that for all we have:

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] Asmussen, S. and Albrecher, H. (2010) Ruin Probabilities. World Scientific, Singapore.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/9789814282536
[2] Rolski, T., Schmidli, H., Schmidt V. and Teugels, J. (2009) Stochastic Processes for Insurance and Finance. John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken.
[3] Albrecher, H., Badescu, A. and Landriault, D. (2008) On the Dual Risk Model with Tax Payments. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 42, 1086-1094.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2008.02.001
[4] Cheung, E.C.K. and Drekic, S. (2008) Dividend Moments in the Dual Risk Model: Exact and Approximate Approaches. Astin Bulletin, 38, 399-422.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2143/AST.38.2.2033347
[5] Yao, D.J., Yang, H.L. and Wang, R.M. (2010) Optimal Financing and Dividend Strategies in a Dual Model with Proportional costs. Journal of Industrial and Management Optimization, 6, 761-777.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3934/jimo.2010.6.761
[6] Zhu, J.X. and Yang, H.L. (2008) Ruin Probabilities of a Dual Markov—Modulated Risk Model. Communications in Statistics—Theory and Methods, 37, 3298-3307.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03610920802117080
[7] Bai, L.H. and Guo, J.Y. (2008) Optimal Proportional Reinsurance and Investment with Multiple Risky Assets and No-Shorting Constraint. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 42, 968-975.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2007.11.002
[8] Browne, S. (1995) Optimal Investment Policies for a Firm with a Random Risk Process: Exponential Utility and Minimizing the Probability of Ruin. Mathematics of Operations Research, 20, 937-958.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/moor.20.4.937
[9] Fleming, W.H. and Hernández, D. (2005) The Tradeoff between Consumption and Investment in Incomplete Financial Markets. Applied Mathematics and Optimization, 52, 219-235.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00245-005-0826-1
[10] Hipp, C. and Plum, M. (2000) Optimal Investment for Insurers. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 27, 215-228.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6687(00)00049-4
[11] Li, Z.F., Zeng, Y. and Lai, Y.Z. (2012) Optimal Time-Consistent Investment and Reinsurance Strategies for Insurers under Heston’s SV Model. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 51, 191-203.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2011.09.002
[12] Zhang, X. and Siu, T.K. (2009) Optimal Investment and Reinsurance of an Insurer with Model Uncertainty. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 45, 81-88.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2009.04.001
[13] French, W.E., Schwert, G.W. and Stambaugh, R.F. (1987) Expected Stock Returns and Volatility. Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 3-29.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(87)90026-2
[14] Pham, H. (2002) Smooth Solutions to Optimal Investment Models with Stochastic Volatilities and Portfolio Constraints. Applied Mathematics and Optimization, 46, 55-78.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00245-002-0735-5
[15] Zariphopoulou, T. (1999) Optimal Investment and Consumption Models with Nonlinear Stock Dynamics. Mathematical Methods of Operations Research, 50, 271-296.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s001860050098
[16] Zariphopoulou, T. (2001) A Solution Approach to Valuation with Unhedgeable Risks. Finance and Stochastics, 5, 61-82.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/PL00000040

Copyright © 2024 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

Creative Commons License

This work and the related PDF file are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.