Journal of Power and Energy Engineering, 2015, 3, 240-249
Published Online April 2015 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/journal/jpee
http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jpee.2015.34033
How to cite this paper: Dong, Y.C. and Zou, B. (2015) A Research of Real-Time Pricing Mechanism and Its Characteristics.
Journal of Power and Energy Engineering, 3, 240-249. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jpee.2015.34033
A Research of Real-Time Pricing Mechanism
and Its Characteristics
Yichao Dong, Bin Zou
School of Mechatronic Engineering and Automation, Shanghai University, Shanghai, China
Email: dyc89m@163.com, zou bin@shu.edu.cn
Received February 2015
Abstract
Real-Time Pricing (RTP) is proposed as an effective Demand-Side Management (DSM) to adjust the
load curve in order to achieve the peak load shifting. At the same time, the RTP mechanism can
also raise the revenue of the supply-side and reduce the electricity expenses of consumers to
achieve a win-win situation. In this paper, a real-time pricing algorithm based on price elasticity
theory is proposed to analyze the energy consumption and the response of the consumers in smart
grid structure. We consider a smart grid equipped with smart meters and two-way communication
system. By using real data to simulate the proposed model, some characteristics of RTP are sum -
marized as follows: 1) Under the condition of the real data, the adjustment of load curve and re-
ducing the expenses of consumers is obviously. But the profit of power supplier is difficult to en-
sure. If we balance the profits of both sides, the supplier and consumers, the profits of both sides
and the adjustment of load curve will be relatively limited. 2) If assuming the response degree of
consumers to real-time prices is high enough, the RTP mechanism can achieve the expected effect.
3, If the cost of supply-side (day-ahead price) fluctuates dramatically, the profits of both sides can
be ensured to achieve the expected effect.
Keywords
Smart Grid, Demand-S ide Manag eme n t, Re al-Time Pricing
1. Introduction
With development of the smart grid, real-time pricing (RTP) is considered as an effective measure of de-
mand -side management (DSM). In a smart environment the information and data transmission between the
power supply-side and demand-side is becoming much more effective. A framework of smart grid that consists
of smart meters, two-way communication, local area network structure, is depicted in Figure 1. Each consumer
is equipped with a smart meter and an energy management system that schedules his/her energy consumption in
response to real-time prices. The meters are connected to the utility through a communication network such as
local area network that allows two-way communication between electricity provider and the meter. With this
capability, besides receiving real-time prices from the electricity provider, the electricity provider would have
access to real-time information on the electricity consumption of each consumer.
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
241
Figure 1. Real-time pricing framework in smart grid.
In traditional power system operation and management, more attention is given to supply-side compared to
demand. Consumers are assumed to be unwilling or incapable of actively changing their consumption behavior.
Therefore, massive demand during on-peak periods leading to higher generation costs. On the other hand, during
off -peak periods, the phenomenon of power redundancy is gradually obvious. In addition to high variability of
market prices, declining reserve margins, transmission congestion, and environmental issues increase the im-
portance of improving the link between supply-side and demand-side [1].
By recent developments on smart metering technologies in smart grid, a number of utilities and states have
executed a variety of time-based pricing programs. For instance, a day-ahea d real-time pricing (DA-RTP) tariff
used by the Illinois Power Company in the United States [2], several critical peak pricing pilots in California,
Idaho, and New Jersey [3], and the three-level (on-peak, mid-peak, off-peak) TOU pricing tariff in Ontario,
Canada [4]. However, recent studies have shown that exposing end-use consumers to hourly real-time prices is
known as the most efficient tool that can urge consumers to consume more wisely and efficiently [5]. Given the
recent increases in energy prices, RTP provides opportunity to consumers to reduce their energy bills by taking
the advantage of lower energy prices in some periods and reducing their consumption when energy prices are
high.
There has been much attention paid to pricing programs in recent years. A novel real-time pricing model
based on smart metering and demand-side management is presented in [1] [6]. The model in [1] is used price
elasticity theory to depict the response degree of consumers. A distributed framework for demand response and
user adaptation in smart grid networks is proposed in [7]. In paper [8] the problem of grid-to-vehicle energy ex-
change between a smart grid and plug-in electric vehicle groups (PEVGs) is studied using a noncooperative
Stackelberg game. In [9] [10], the formulation and critical assessment of a novel type of demand response pro-
gram targeting retail customers who are equipped with smart meters yet still face a flat rate.
2. Mathematical Formulation
2.1. Objective Fun cti o n
The objective function is formulated as (1) here. It aims to maximize the energy provider’s profits, which is de-
fined as the difference between its revenue due to selling energy to consumers and the cost of purchasing energy
from the day-ahead electricity market.
( )( )( )( )
24
11
Max
n
c csub E
tc
dttp tt
ρρ
= =






∑∑
(1)
whe r e
( )
sub
Pt
is the amount of power purchased by the energy provider from DA energy market at Hour t;
( )
E
t
ρ
is the DA energy market price at Hour t;
( )
c
dt
is the consumption that customer response to the
real-time prices at Hour t;
( )
c
t
ρ
is the real-time price at Hour t; and n is the number of consumers.
In this paper, the demand response model is set by using price elasticity theory. The self and cross elasticity
represent the response of consumers at each period respectively.
Consumer response to RTP:
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
242
()( )()( )( )
()( )( )( )
( )
24
00
01
00
1,
cc ccc
cc c
h
cc
ht
tt th h
d tdtth
th
ερ ρρρ
ε
ρρ
=

−−
 

 
=++



(2)
where
( )
c
t
ε
and
are self and cross price elasticity of the demand respectively;
( )
0c
t
ρ
is base
energy price set by the historical data;
( )
0c
dt
is the initial demand forecast.
2.2. Constraints
Constrains are composed of following several components. The first is the load flow of the power grid. The
feeders flow limits (3), bus voltage limits (4) and grid ramping constraints (7) are taken into account in the mod-
el. Secondly, implementing RTP is in order to change the consumption habit of consumers, not to reduce the
power consumption. So the limits on daily consumption (5) ensure the consumption is unchanged after imple-
menting the RTP model. As mentioned in (6), the real-time prices have to be considered hedge consumers
against high energy prices. The last constraints ensure the profits of consumers (8).
Subject to:
Feeders flow limits:
( )
max
,,
,
t ijttt ij
SV S
δ
(3)
,
t ij
S
is the apparent power flow between node i and j;
t
V
and
t
δ
is voltage amplitude and voltage angle;
max
,t ij
S
is the capacity of the line between node i and j.
Bus voltage limits:
min max
, ,,titi ti
V VV≤≤
(4)
min
,ti
V
and
max
,ti
V
are maximum and minimum voltage magnitude at node i.
Limit on daily consumption:
( )
24 day
1cc
t
dt d
=
=
(5)
day
c
d
is the daily consumption set by historical data.
Price limits:
( )( )( )
min max
c cc
ttt
ρ ρρ
≤≤
(6)
( )
max
c
t
ρ
and
is the price cap and the price floor of the RTP.
Grid ramping constraint:
( )()
-1 -1
70% 130%
tt t
SS S≤≤
(7)
The constraint represents the power amplitude is pegged at 30 per cent between two neighboring hours.
Limit on consumers’ revenue:
( )( )( )( )
24 24
00
11
ccc c
tt
dttd tt
ρρ
= =
<
∑∑
(8)
The constraint represents the expenses of consumers are reduced by implementing RTP. Consumers enjoy a
low price when they respond the RTP actively.
3. Numerical Case Study
3.1. Simulated Netwo rk
The proposed model is simulated in a 33-node radial distribution system shown in Figure 2 references [12]. The
loads in this system are characterized based on consumer type. Each consumer belongs to one of the 4 categories
(residential, commercial, industrial and some new type of power consumers). Consumers are divided into 4 cat-
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
243
egories in Table 1. The new type of power consumers is considered as a group of users who respond to the RTP
more actively than the other type of consumers, such as charging of electric vehicles, etc. which is introduced in
[11]. References [13]-[15] the self and cross elasticity of different consumers in shown in Table 2. On-peak time
is (7 - 11, 17 - 19), mid-peak is (11 - 17), off-peak is (19 - 7).
3.2. Simulation Data
The power market data of this paper is from Ontario, Canada. Feb.4.2011. The average market prices during
February and August were 3.3 ¢/kWh and 3.5 ¢/kWh, respectively. The average global adjustments were
3.5 ¢/kWh and 3.6 ¢/kWh during February and August 2011, respectively. Therefore, average RPP prices were
Figure 2. IEEE 33-node distribution network.
Table 1. Load types at different buses of the 33-node distribution test system.
Type of consumer load buses
Residential 2, 4,5, 8, 9, 10, 12, 14 , 15, 16, 17 , 18, 19, 20, 21, 2 5, 26, 27, 3 0, 31, 32
Commercial 1, 3, 6, 7, 13, 28
Industrial 23, 24
New type of consumers 11, 22, 31
Table 2. The self and cross elasticity of different consumers in 24 hours.
Type of consumers on peak mid peak off peak
residential
on peak 0.15 0.08 0.07
mid peak 0.08 0.13 0.05
off peak 0.07 0.05 0.12
commercial on peak 0.13 0.05 0.08
mid peak 0.05 0.13 0.08
off peak 0.08 0.08 0.16
indus trial on peak 0.13 0.08 0.05
mid peak 0.08 0.13 0.06
off peak 0.05 0.06 0.16
New types of consumers
on peak 0.22 0.10 0.12
mid peak 0.10 0.17 0.07
off peak 0.12 0.07 0.19
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
244
6.8 ¢/kWh and 7.1 ¢/kWh during February and August 2011, respectively as reported in [13]-[16]. The average
RPP prices are assumed as base energy price (tariff) in the numerical studies. The load curve and day-ahead
price is shown in Figure 3 and Figure 4.
3.3. Simulation Results
The simulation is assumed that all the nodes of test system are the residential, industrial, commercial and new
type of consumers respectively. Then demand curve data is shown in Figure 5-8. Then add a weight value ac-
cording to the Table 2. to calculate the data of whole society (33-node) in Figure 9. The proposed model is si-
mulated in Matlab with yalmip toolbox which is based on primal-dual interior point algorithm.
Figure 3. Daily demand curves (Ontario Canada) Feb.4th.2011.
Figure 4. Day-ahead price (Ontario Canada) Feb.4th. 2011.
Figure 5. Daily demand curve (residential).
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
245
Figure 6. Daily demand curve (industrial).
Figure 7. Daily demand curve (commercial).
Figure 8. Daily demand curve (new type of consumer such as electric vehicle).
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
246
The blue line is the original load curve and the red one is the load data of response to RTP model. Residential
consumers are willing to shift more load from on-peak time (7 A.M -11 A.M) to off-peak (7 P.M.-6 A.M.) than
industrial and commercial. Commercial consumers are willing to shift more load from on-peak time to mi d-peak
(11 A.M. -5 P.M.) and the load shifting of industrial from on-peak to off-peak and mid-peak is relative to the av-
erage. The new type of power consumers like electric vehicle is considered as a high elasticity group in 5 P.M.
to 6 A.M. Because of the charging of electric vehicle will be controlled by smart meter in the future in reference
[11]. Due to the new type of consumers is set by a higher elasticity than other categories, the shifting of the load
curve is more obvious. By adding the weight value, the curve data of whole society is shown as follow: The load
is shifted about 1.47% during on-peak time and the load of off-peak and mid-peak is increased about 1.69% and
0.16% respectively. The real-time prices are shown in Figure 10. The electricity bills of consumers are reduced
about 0.49%, but the profits of supply side are also reduced about 0.88%. So that is not a expected result. If we
set a constraint that the profits of supply side must be raised, then there is no optimal solution in this simulation.
In the follow section three cases are proposed to analyze the model in which situations the real-time pricing
model can ensure the profits of supply-side to achieve the expected result.
4. Further Analysis of the Simulation Result
The initial result is not expected because of the profits of supply-side can be ensure even with the risk of loss.
Therefore, there are some limitations to the real-time pricing mechanism. Three cases are proposed to analyze
the RTP in which situations can achieve a win-win situation.
Figure 9. Daily demand curve (whole society 33-node).
Figure 10. Real-time prices in 24 hours.
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
247
4.1. Raise the Range of Real-Time Prices to Balance the Profits between Two Sides
Due of the RTP is different value for each kind of consumers, such as residential, industrial and commercial
consumers. In the case of the same model and data, we adjust the fluctuation range of the RTP to 95% - 115% of
the historical feed-in tariff (raised from 90% - 110%). The load curve is show in Figu re 11. The profits of
supply-side is increased about 0.03% and the electric expense of consumers is reduced about 0.06%. The simu-
lation result achieves expected effect preliminarily, but the profits of both sides and the adjustment of load curve
is relatively limited. The peak-shift of the load curve is not obvious as the RTP model set as 90% - 110%. The
on-peak load is shifted about 0.9% and the off-peak load is increased about 0.75%. The prices data is shown in
Figure 12.
4.2. The High Enough Elasticity Leads to Expected Result
Obviously, the higher price elasticity is better for the result of RTP simulation. Thus, if we choose a part of
consumers to simulate RTP mechanism who get high elasticities means they respond to RTP more actively, it
can achieve the expected result. When the elasticity is set about 0.4 - 0.45, the load curve is shown in Figure 13.
The profits of supply-side are increased about 0.15% and the electricity expenses of consumers are reduced
about 0.28%. The adjustment of the load curve is remarkable. The on-peak load is shifted about 2.12% and the
off -peak load is increased about 3.03%. The prices data is shown in Figure 14.
Fig ure 11. The load curve adjusted by the range of prices.
Fig ure 12. The real-times prices adjusted by the range of prices.
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
248
Fig ure 13. The load curve adjusted by elastics.
Fig ure 14. The real-times prices adjusted by elastics.
4.3. Suitable Day-Ahead Prices Ensure the Profits of Supply-Side
From the previous simulation result, the load curve and the profits of consumers can achieve the expected effect.
But the revenue of the supply-side is difficult to be ensured. Therefore, the cost of supply-side is worth for fur-
ther analysis. If the day-ahead market price fluctuates more extremely, it suits RTP better. With the same model
and power system data, the on-peak prices and off-peak prices of day-ahead market is set about 2.7:1 (on-peak:
off -peak). The profits of the supply side are increased about 0.17%, and the load curve and the profits of con-
sumers can achieve the expected effect as before.
5. Conclusion
Under the background of real-time pricing model based on price electricity theory, the simulation by using real
data shows RTP is competent in peak load shifting to adjust the load curve. Due to the demand response of con-
sumers, electricity bills of the active consumers are reduced dramatically. But the profits of the supply-side
cannot be ensured even with a risk of loss. Three cases are proposed to analyze in which situations RTP will
achieve the expected result. 1) If we balance the profits of both sides, the supplier and consumers, the profits of
both sides and the adjustment of load curve will be relatively limited. 2) If assuming the response of consumers
to real-time prices is active enough, the RTP mechanism can achieve the expected effect. 3) If the cost of the
power supplier (day-ahead prices) fluctuates dramatically, the profits of both sides can be ensured to achieve the
expected result.
Y. C. Dong, B. Zou
249
References
[1] Doostizadeh, M. and Ghas emi, H. (2012) A Day-Ahead Electricity Pricing Model Based on Smart Metering and De-
mand-Side Management. Energy, 46, 221 -230. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2012.08.029
[2] Ameren Services (2012) R eal-Time Pricing for Residential Customers.
http ://www.amer en.co m/sites/ai u/ Electr icCho ice/P ages/ResReal TimeP ri cing. aspx
[3] Edison Electric Institute (2012) Retail Electricity Pricing and Rate Design in Evolving Markets.
http://www.eei.org/ourissues/electricitydistribution/Documents/Retail-Electricity-Pricing.pdf; Ontario Energy Board
(OEB), Ontario, Canada. http://www.ontarioenergyboard.ca/OEB/Consumers/Electricity/ElectricityþPrices
[4] Samad i, P., Mohsenian-Rad, A., Schober, R., Wong, V. and Jatskevich, J. (2010) Optimal Real -Time Pricing Algo-
rithm Based on Utility Maximization for Smart Grid. First IEEE International Conference on Smart Grid Communica-
tions (Smart GridComm).
[5] Alexan der, B. (2007) Smart Met ers, Real Time Pricing, and Demand Response Programs: Implications for Low In-
come Electric Customers. Oak Ridge Natl. Lab., Tech. Rep. http://www.smartgridinformation.info/pdf/2438-doc-1.pdf
[6] Zhong, F. (2012) A Distributed Demand Response Algorithm and Its Application to PHEV Charging in Smart Grids.
IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 3.
[7] Tushar, W., Saad, W., Poor, H.V. and Smith, D.B. (2012 ) Economics of Electric Vehicle Charging: A Game Theoretic
Approach. IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 3.
[8] Li , P.Q., Y in g, J., Zhang, A., Huang, J.W. and Wu, Y. (2013) Demand Response Management via Real-Ti me Electri c-
ity Price Control in Smart Grids. IEEE Journal on Selected Areas in Communications, 31.
[9] Weckx, S. and Driesen , J. Optimal Real-Time Pricing for Unbalanced Distribution Grids with Network Constraints.
[10] Zhong, H.W., Xie, L. and Xia, Q. (2013) Coupon Incentive-Based Demand Response: Theory and Case Study. IEEE
Transactions on Power Systems, 28. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/TPWRS.2012.2218665
[11] Qian, K.J., Zhou, C.K., Allan, M. and Yuan, Y. (2011) Modeling of Load Demand Due to EV Battery Charging in
Distribution System. IEEE Transactions on power system, 26. http: //d x.do i .org/ 10. 1109 /TP WR S. 2010 .205 74 56
[12] Baran, M.E. and Wu, F.F. (1989) Network Reconfiguration in Distribution Systems for Loss Reduction and Load Ba-
lancin g. IEEE Transactions on Power Delivery, 4.
[13] Deal, K. (2012) Assessing Whether Firm Day-Ahead Prices Lead to Changes in Elasticity of Demand and Greater
Customer Efficiencies. h ttp://www.ieso.ca/imoweb/pubs/mear/Deal-Mountain-Report-April2008.pdf
[14] US Department of Energy (2006) Benefits of Demand Response in Electricity Markets and Recommendations for
Achieving Them. Report to the United States Congress. http://eetd.lbl.gov/EA/EMS/reports/congress-1252d.pdf
[15] Independent Electricity System Operator (IESO), Ontario, Canada. http://www.ieso.ca/; G AM S . Development Corpo-
ration, General algebraic modeling system (GAMS). http://www.gams.com; CONOPT Solver.
http://www.gams.com/dd/docs/solvers/conopt.pdf
[16] Ontario Energy Board (OEB). Regulated Price Plan Manual .
http://www.ontarioenergyboard.ca/OEB/Documents/EB-2004-0205/RPP -Manual.pdf