Journal of Mathematical Finance
Vol.05 No.02(2015), Article ID:55769,12 pages
10.4236/jmf.2015.52012

On the Study of Reduced-Form Approach and Hybrid Model for the Valuation of Credit Risk

Olaronke Helen Edogbanya1, Sunday Emmanuel Fadugba2

1Department of Mathematics, Federal University, Lokoja, Nigeria

2Department of Mathematical Sciences, Ekiti State University, Ado Ekiti, Nigeria

Email: helyna4christ@yahoo.com, emmasfad2006@yahoo.com,

Copyright © 2015 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Received 10 June 2014; accepted 16 April 2015; published 17 April 2015

ABSTRACT

This paper presents the study of reduced-form approach and hybrid model for the valuation of credit risk. Credit risk arises whenever a borrower is expecting to use future cash flows to pay a current debt. It is closely tied to the potential return of investment, the most notable being that the yields on bonds correlate strongly to their perceived credit risk. Credit risk embedded in a financial transaction, is the risk that at least one of the parties involved in the transaction will suffer a financial loss due to decline in creditworthiness of the counter-party to the transaction or perhaps of some third party. Reduced-form approach is known as intensity-based approach. This is purely probabilistic in nature and technically speaking it has a lot in common with the reliability theory. Here the value of firm is not modeled but specifically the default risk is related either by a deterministic default intensity function or more general by stochastic intensity. Hybrid model combines the structural and intensity-based approaches. While avoiding their difficulties, it picks the best features of both approaches, the economic and intuitive appeal of the structural approach and the tractability and empirical fit of the intensity-based approach.

Keywords:

Credit Risk, Hybrid Model, Reduced-Form Approach, Risk-Neutral Valuation Formula

1. Introduction

As stock markets have become more sophisticated, so have their products. The simple buy or sell trades of the early markets have been replaced by more complex financial options and derivatives. These contracts can give investors various opportunities to tailor their deals to their investment needs.

The main emphasis in the intensity-based approach is put on the modelling of the random time of default, as well as evaluating condition expectations under a risk-neutral probability of functionals of the default time and corresponding cash follows. Typically, the random default time is defined as the jump time of some one-jump process.

In recent years, we see a spectacular growth in trading, especially in derivative instruments. There is also an increasing complexity of products in the financial markets with the growing complexity and trading size of financial markets; mathematical models have come to play an increasingly important role in financial decision making, especially in the context of pricing and hedging of derivative instruments. Models have become indispensable tools in the development of new financial products and the management of their risks.

Credit risk is defined as the changes in the credit quality of a borrower. This is called the spread risk. If a borrower has a lower quality ranking we expect that he will be less able to pay off his running-up debt. Therefore credit risk is characterized by two risks: default risk and spread risk. The importance of valuation and hedging models in derivatives markets cannot be over-emphasized. The financial risk can therefore be categorized into four (4) types namely: Market risk, Liquidity risk, Operational risk and Credit risk.

The first category of credit risk models are the ones based on the original framework developed by Merton [1] . They derived an explicit formula for risky bonds which can be used both to estimate the probability of default of a firm and to estimate the yield differential between a risk bond and a default-free bond. In addition to Merton [1] , first generation structure-firm models include Black and Cox [2] . They try to refine the original Merton framework by removing one or more of the unrealistic assumptions. Black and Cox [2] introduced the possibility of more complex capital structure with subordinated debts, using the principles of option pricing Black and Scholes [3] . In such a framework, the default process of a company is driven by the value of the company’s assets and the risk of a firm’s default is therefore explicitly linked to the variability of the firm’s asset value. The basic intuition behind the Merton model is that, default occurs when the value of a firm’s assets (the market value of the firm) is lower than that of its liabilities.

Reduced-form models somewhat differ from each other by the manner in which the recovery rate is parameterized. For example, Jarrow and Turnbull [4] assumed that, at default, a bond would have a market value equal to an exogenous specified fraction of an otherwise equivalent default-free bond. Duffie and Lando [5] would have a market value equal to an exogenously specified fraction of an otherwise equivalent default-free bond. Duffie and Singleton [6] followed with a model that when market value at default (recovery rate) is exogenously specified, allows for closed-form solutions for term-structure of credit spreads. Hybrid model is the combination of ideas from both the structural and intensity-based approaches; this is by postulating that the hazard rate of default (intensity) event is directly linked to the current value of the firm’s assets (or the firm’s equity).

For mathematical background, valuation of credit risk, some numerical method for options valuation and stochastic analysis based on the Ito integral, see [7] -[20] , just to mention a few. This paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the reduced-form model. Section 3 discusses hazard processes. Section 4 presents hybrid model for the valuation of credit risk. Section 5 concludes the paper. In this paper we shall consider reduced- form approach and hybrid model for the valuation of credit risk.

2. Reduced-Form Model

In this approach, the value of the firm’s assets and its capital structure are not model at all, and the credit events are specified in terms of some exogenously specified jump process (as a rule, the recovery rates at default are also given exogenously). We can distinguish between the reduced-form models that are only concerned with the modelling of default time, and that are henceforth referred to as the intensity-based models, and the reduced form models with migrations between credit rating classes called the credit migration models.

The main emphasis in the intensity-based approach is put on the modelling of the random time of default, as well as evaluating condition expectations under a risk-neutral probability of functionals of the default time and corresponding cash follows. Typically, the random default time is defined as the jump time of some one-jump process. As well shall see, a pivotal role in evaluating respective conditional expectations is played by the default intensity process.

Modelling of the intensity process which is also known as the hazard rate process, is the starting point in the intensity approach.

2.1. Hazard Function

Before going deeper in the analysis of the reduced-form approach, we shall first examine a related technical

question. Suppose we want to evaluate a conditional expectation, where τ is a stopping time on

a probability space, with respect to some filtration and Y is an integrable, -measura- ble random variable for some.

In financial applications, it is quite natural and convenient to model the filtration G as G = FVH, where h is the filtration that carries full information about default events (that is, events such as), whereas the reference filtration F carries information about other relevant financial and economic processes, but, typically, it does not carry full information about default event. The first question we address is how to compute the expectation

(2.1)

Using the intensity of τ with respect to F.

2.1.1. Hazard Function of a Random Time

We study the case where the reference filtration F is trivial, so that it does not carry any information whatsoever. Consequently, we have that G = h. Arguably, this is the simplest possible used in practical financial applications, as it leads to relatively easy calibration of the model.

We start by recalling the notion of a hazard function of a random time. Let τ be a finite, non-negative random time.

Let τ be a finite, non-negative, variable on a probability space, referred to as the random time. We assume that and τ is unbounded;

(2.2)

The right continuous cumulative distribution function F of τ satisfies

(2.3)

We also assume that so that τ is a Markov time.

We introduce the right-continuous jump process and we write to denote the (right continuous and p-completed) filtration generated by the process H. Of course, τ is an h-stopping time.

We shall assume throughout that all random variables and processes that are used in what follows satisfy suitable integrability conditions. We begin with the following simple and important result.

Lemma 1

For any -measurable (integrable) random variable Y we have

(2.4)

For any -measurable random variable Y we have

(2.5)

that is, for a Borel measurable which is constant on the interval.

The hazard function is introduced through the following definition.

Definition 1: The increasing right-continuous function given by the formula

(2.6)

is called the hazard function of a random time τ.

If the distribution function F is an absolutely continuous function, i.e., if we have

for some function, then we have

where we set

is a non-negative function and it satisfies.

The function is called the hazard rate or intensity of τ sometimes, in order to emphasize relevance of the measure p the terminology p-hazard rate and p-intensity is used. The next result follows from definition 2.

Definition 2: The dividend process D of a defaultable contingent claim, which settles at time T, equals

D is a process of finite variation and

Note that if default occurs at some date t, the promised dividend, which is due to be paid at this date, is not received by the holder of a defaultable claim. Furthermore, if we set then

(2.7)

Remark: In principle, the promised payoff X could be incorporated into the promised dividends process C. However, this would inconvenient, since in practice the recovery rules concerning the promised dividend C as the promised claim X are different, in general. For instance, in the case of a defaultable coupon bond, it is frequently postulated that in case of default the future coupons are lost, but a strictly positive fraction of the face value is usually received by the bondholder.

Corollary 2: For any -measurable random variable Y we have

(2.8)

Corollary 3: Let Y be -measurable, so that for some function. If the hazard func- tion Γ is continuous then

(2.9)

If, in addition, the random time τ admits the hazard rate function γ then we have

(2.10)

In particular, for any we have:

(2.11)

and

(2.12)

Lemma 4: The process L, given by the formula

is an h-martingale.

2.1.2. Martingales Associated with Continuous Hazard Function

The h-adapted process of finite variation L given by last formula is an h-martingale (for Γ continuous or a discontinuous function).

We examine further important examples of martingales associated with the hazard function, with the assumption that the hazard function Γ of a random time τ is continuous. Also we assume that the cumulative distribution function F is absolutely continuous function, so that the random time τ admits the intensity function γ, our goal is to establish a martingale characterization of γ.

More specifically, we shall check directly that the process, defined as:

follows and h-martingale. To this end,

On the other hand, if we denote

Let us set. Using the Fubini’s theorem, we obtain

(2.13)

This shows that the process follows an h-martingale.

2.1.3. Martingale Hazard Function

Lemma 5: Assume that F (and this also the Hazard function Γ) is continuous function. Then the process

(2.14)

is h-martingale.

In view of the martingale in Lemma 5, the following definition is natural.

Definition 3: A function is called a martingale hazard function of a random time τ with respect to the filtration if and only if the process

Remarks: Since the bounded, increasing process H is constant after time τ its compensation is constant after τ as well. This explains why the function has to be evaluated at time, rather than at time t. H is thus a bounded h-submartingale.

It happens that the martingale hazard function can be found explicitly. In fact, we have the following.

Proposition 6: The unique martingale hazard function of τ with respect to the filtration h is the right-conti- nuous increasing function given by the formula

(2.15)

(2.16)

Observe that the martingale hazard function is continuous if and only if F is continuous. In this case, we have

(2.17)

We conclude that the martingale hazard function coincides with the hazard function Γ if and only if F is a continuous function.

In general, we have

(2.18)

where

(2.19)

2.2. Default Table Bonds: Deterministic Intensity

In order to value a defaultable claim, we need, of course, to specify the unit in which we would like to express all prices. Formally, this is done through a choice of discount factor (a numeraire). For the sake of simplicity, we shall take the savings account

(2.20)

as the numraire, where r is the short term interest rate process.

We also postulate that some probability measure is a martingale measure relative to this nomeraire. This assumption means, in particular, that the price of any contingent claim Y which settles at time T is given as the conditional expectation.

In accordance with our assumption that the reference filtration is trivial, we also assume that:

・ the default time τ admits the -intensity function;

・ the short-term interest rate is a deterministic function of time.

In view of the latter assumption, the price at time t of a unit default-free zero-coupon bond of maturity T equals

(2.21)

In the market practice, the interest rate (more precisely, the yield curve) can be derived from the market price of the zero-coupon bond. In a similar way the hazard rate can be deduced from the prices of the corporate zero- coupon bonds, or from the market values of other actively traded credit derivatives.

In view of our earlier notation for defaultable claims adopted, for the corporate unit discount bond we have and. And since the reference filtration is assumed trivial, we have that.

2.3. Zero Recovery

Consider first a corporate zero-coupon bond with unit face value, the maturity date T, and zero recovery at default (that is, and). Finally, the bond can thus be identified with a claim of the form which settle at T. It is clear that a corporate bond with zero recovery becomes worthless as soon as default occurs. Its time t price is defined as

The price can be represented as follows:

(2.22)

where is the bond’s pre-default value, and is given by the formula

(2.23)

2.3.1. Fractional Recovery of Par Value (FRPV)

According to this convention, we have and the recovery process Z satisfy for some constant recovery rate. This means that under FRPV the bondholder receives at time of default a fixed fraction of bond’s par value.

Using Corollary 3, we check that the pre-default value of a unit corporate zero-coupon bond with FRPV equals

(2.24)

where is the default risk-adjusted interest rate. Since the fraction of the par value is received at the time of default, in the case of full recovery, that is, for, we do not obtain the equality but rather the inequality (at least when the interest rate is strictly positive, so that for.

2.3.2. Fractional Recovery of Treasury Value (FRTV)

Assume now that and that the recovery process equal. This means that the recovery payoff at the time of default represent a fraction of the price of the (equivalent) Treasury bond. The price of a corporate bond which is subject to this recovery scheme equals

Let us denote by the pre-default value of a unit corporate bond subject to the FRTV scheme. Then

or equivalently,

(2.25)

In the case of full recovery, that is, for, we obtain as expected.

Remarks. Similar representations can be derived also in the case when the reference filtration F is not trivial, and under the assumption that market risk and credit risk are independent that is:

・ the default time admits the F-intensity process γ,

・ the interest rate process r is independent of the filtration F.

3. Hazard Processes

In the previous section, it was assumed that the reference filtration F carries no information. However, for practical purposes it is important to study the situation where the reference filtration is not trivial. This section presents some results to this effect.

We assume that a martingale measure Q is given, and examine the valuation of defaultable contingent claims under this probability measure. Note that the defaultable market is incomplete if there are no defaultable assets traded on the market that are sensitive to the same default risk as the defaultable contingent claim we wish to price. Thus, the martingale measure may not be unique.

3.1. Hazard Process of a Random Time

Let be a finite, non-negative random variable on a probability space. Assume for some reference filtration F, so that.

We start by extending some definitions and results to the present framework. We denote, so that is the survival process with respect to F. F is a bonded non-negative, F-sub- martingale. As a submartingale, this process admits a Doob-Meter decomposition as where A is an F-predictable increasing process. Assume, in addition, that for every.

Definition 4: The F-hazard process Γ of a random time τ is defined through the equality, that is,.

Notice that the existence of Γ implies that τ is not an F-stopping time. If the event belongs to the - field for some then (p-almost surely) and this.

If the hazard process is absolutely continuous, so that, for some process γ, then γ is called the F-intensity of τ. Thus the case only if the process Γ is increasing and thus γ is always non-negative. Note that if the reference filtration F is trivial, then the hazard process Γ is the same as the hazard function. In this case, if T is absolutely continuous, then we have.

3.2. Terminal Payoff

The valuation of the terminal payoff is based on the following generalization of Lemma 1.

The question is how to compute for and -measurable random variable Y?

Lemma 7: For any -measurable (integrable) random variable Y an arbitrary we have

(3.1)

If, in addition, Y is -measurable then

(3.2)

Assume that Y is -measurable. Then there exists on -measurable random variable such that

.

The latter property can be extended to stochastic process: for any G-predictable process X there exists an F- predictable process such that the equality

(3.3)

is valid for every, that both processes coincides on the random interval.

3.3. Recovery Process

The following extension of Corollary 3 appears to be useful in the valuation of the recovery payoff (Note that the payoff occurs at time τ).

Lemma 8: Assume that the hazard process Γ is a continuous, increasing process, and let Z be a bonded, F-predictable process. Then for any we have:

(3.4)

3.4. Promised Dividends

To value the promised dividends (that are paid prior to τ, it is convenient to make use of the following result.

Lemma 9: Assume that the hazard process Γ is continuous. Let C be a bounded, F-predictable process of finite variation. Then for event

(3.5)

3.5. Valuation of Defaultable Claims

We assume that τ is given on a filtered probability spaces, where and for every so that the F-hazard process Γ of τ under is well define. A default time τ is thus a G- stopping time, but it is an F-stopping time.

The probability is assumed to be a martingale measure relative to saving account process B, which is given by (3) for some F-progressively measurable process r. In some sense, this probability, and thus also the F-hazard process Γ of τ under, are given by the market via calibration.

The ex-dividend price of a defaultable claim is given by definition 5 below.

Definition 5: For any date, the ex-dividend price of the defaultable claim is given as

(3.6)

we always set. With substituted with and F replaced by G. We postulate in particular, that the processes Z and C are F-predictable, and the random variable X and are -measurable and - measurable, respectively. Using Lemmas 7, 8, 9 and the fact that the savings account process B is F-adapted, a convenient representation for the arbitrage price of a defaultable claim in terms of the F-hazard process Γ is derived.

Proposition 10: The value process of a defaultable claim admits the following representation for

If the hazard process Γ is an increasing, continuous process, then

Corollary 11: Assume that the F-hazard process Γ is a continuous, increasing process. Then the value process of a defaultable contingent claim coincides with the value process of a claim, where we set.

3.6. Defaultable Bonds: Stochastic Intensity

Consider a defaultable zero-coupon bond with the par (face) value L and maturity date T. First, we re-examine the following recovery schemes: the fractional recovery of par value and the fractional recovery of Treasury value. Subsequently, we shall deal with the fractional recovery of pre-default value, but in this section using the stochastic intensity instead of the deterministic intensity used earlier. We assume that τ has the E-intensity γ.

3.7. Functional Recovery of Par Value

Under this scheme, a fixed fraction of the face value of the bond is paid to the bondholders at the time of default. Formally, we deal here with a defaultable claim, which settle at time T. With the promised payoff, where L stands for the bond’s face value, and with the recovery process, where is a constant. The value at time of the bond is given by the expression

(3.7)

If τ admits the F-intensity γ, the pre-default value of the bond equals

(3.8)

Remarks. The above setup is a special case of the fractional recovery of par value scheme with a general F- predictable recovery process, where the process satisfies, for every. A general version of formula (3.8) is given by

(3.9)

3.8. Fractional Recovery of Treasury Value

Here, in the case of default, the fixed fraction of the face value is paid to bondholders at maturity date T. A corporate zero-coupon bond is now represented by a defaultable claim with the promised payoff and the recovery process. stands for the price at time t of unit zero-coupon Treasury bond with Maturity T. The corporate bond is now equivalent to a single contingent claim Y, which settle at time T and equals

(3.10)

The price of this claim oat time equals

(3.11)

or equivalently,

(3.12)

The pre-default value of defaultable bond with the fractional recovery of Treasury value equals

(3.13)

Again, the last formula is special case of the general situation where with some predictable recovery ratio process.

3.9. Fractional Recovery of Pre-Default Value

Assume that is some predictable recovery ratio process and let us set. The pre-default value of the bond equals

(3.14)

where

(3.15)

3.10. Choice of a Recovery Scheme

A challenging practical problem is the calibration of statistical properties of both the recovery process δ and the intensity process γ. The empirical evidence strongly suggests that the amount recovered at default is best modelled by the recovery of par value scheme. However, we conclude that recovery concept that specifies the amount recovered as fraction of appropriately discounted par value, that is, the fractional recovery of treasury value, has broader empirical support.

4. Hybrid Model

This is basically combination of ideas from both the structural and intensity-based approaches, this is by postulating that the hazard rate of default (intensity) event is directly linked to the current value of the firm’s assets (or the firm’s equity). Reduced-form models with this specific feature are referred to as hybrid model. In this setup, the default time is still a totally inaccessible stopping time, but the likelihood of default may grow rapidly when the total value of the firm’s assets approaches some barrier. Madan and Unal [20] consider the discounted equity value (including reinvested dividends) process as the unique Markovian state variable in their intensity-based model.

They postulate that the hazard rate of default equals or simply for some function. The process is assumed to follow a diffusion process, specifically

(4.1)

Under the martingale measure and for some constant volatility coefficient. We assume that the process takes on strictly positive values: for every. The default time τ is given by the canonical construction, so that it is defined on an enlarged probability space. a standard Brownian motion under and is an extension of.

We take a function, where c and are strictly positive constants. It is interesting to

notice that the stochastic intensity tends to infinity when the discounted equity value approaches, either form above or from below, the critical level. To avoid making a particular choice of default-free term structure model, we focus on the futures price of a corporate bond.

The futures price of a contingent claim X, for the settlement date T, is given by the conditional expectation under the spot martingale measure;

(4.2)

In particular, the futures price of a defaultable bond with zero recovery is given by the formula

(4.3)

More explicitly,

for some function.

By virtue of Equation (4.1) and the Feynman-Kao theorem, the function r satisfies, under mild technical assumptions, the following pricing partial differential equation

(4.4)

subject to the terminal condition. For the sake of notational simplicity, we assumed here that is one dimensional. Under these assumptions the futures price of a corporate bond is given by

(4.5)

where the parameter v satisfies and

(4.6)

For a fixed value of the parameter v, the function satisfies the second-order ordinary differential equation

(4.7)

with the initial conditions and. The quasi-explicit valuation formula above may

serve to produce estimates of parameters of the hazard rate process, based on the observed market yields on defaultable bonds.

5. Conclusion

We have in our disposal two models for the valuation of credit risk named the reduced-form model and the hybrid model. It is worth noting that the cornerstone of credit risk and its modelling is based on the information one can perceive. This information can be complete (structural approach), partial (incomplete information model which is called hybrid model) or not available (reduced-form model). This perceived information defined the methodology that one can apply to model credit risk. Everything lies on whether information is available or not. And that is the very fundamental economic notion of credit risk. We conclude this paper by commenting on the advantages and disadvantages of the reduced-form model and the hybrid model for the valuation of credit risk.

5.1. Advantages of Reduced-Form Model

・ The level of the credit risk is reflected in a single quantity: the risk-neutral default intensity.

・ The random time of default is an unpredictable stopping time, and thus the default event comes as an almost total surprise.

・ The valuation of defaultable claims is rather straightforward. It resembles the valuation of default-free contingent claims in term structure models, through well understood techniques.

・ Credit spreads are much easier to quantify and manipulate than in structural models of credit risk. Consequently, the credit spreads are more realistic and risk premia are easier to handle.

・ The intensity of the random time of default plays the role of a models input.

・ Valuation result for corporate bonds and credit derivatives are relatively simple, even in the case of basket credit derivatives.

・ In practice, the intensity of default can be inferred from observed prices of bonds (the calibrated or implied default intensity).

5.2. Disadvantages of Reduced-Form Model

・ Value of the firm is not explicitly modelled.

・ Typically, current data regarding the level of the firm’s assets and the firm’s leverage are not taken into account.

・ Specific features related to safety covenants and debt’s seniority are not easy to handle.

・ All (important) issues related to the capital structure of a firm are beyond the scope of this approach.

・ Most practical approaches to portfolio’s credit risk are linked to the value-of-the-firm approach.

5.3. Advantages of Hybrid Model

・ This is basically combination of ideas from both the structural and intensity based approaches. While avoiding their difficulties, it picks the best features of both approaches: the economic and intuitive appeal of the structural approach and the tractability and empirical fit of the intensity-based approach.

・ Hybrid model is of great importance in credit risk valuation because of the existence of a bankruptcy process.

・ Dependent defaults are easy to handle through correlation of processes corresponding to different names.

5.4. Disadvantages of Hybrid Model

・ A stringent assumption that the total value of the firm’s assets can be easily observed. In practice, continuous-time observations of the value processes are not available. Thus the structural model with incomplete accounting data can be dealt with using the intensity-based methodology.

・ Most practical approaches to portfolio’s credit risk are linked to the value-of-the-firm approach.

References

  1. Merton, R.C. (1974) On the Pricing of Coporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates. Journal of Finance, 29, 449-470.
  2. Black, F. and Cox, J.C. (1976) Valuing Corporate Securities: Some Effects of Bond Indenture Provisions. Journal of Finance, 31, 351-367. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1976.tb01891.x
  3. Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973) The Pricing of Options and Coporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637-654. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/260062
  4. Jarrow, R.A. and Turnbull, S.M. (1995) Pricing Derivatives on Financial Securities Subject to Credit Risk. The Journal of Finance, 1, 53-85. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb05167.x
  5. Duffie, D. and Lando, D. (2001) The Term Structure of Credit Spreads with Incomplete According Information, Econometrica, 69, 633-664. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00208
  6. Duffie, D. and Singleton, K. (1999) Credit Risk Pricing and Risk Management for Financial Institutions. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
  7. Ammann, M. (1999) Pricing Derivative Credit Risk. Springer-Verlag, New York.
  8. Crouly, M., Galev, D. and Mark, R. (1998) Credit Risk Revisited, Risk-Credit Risk Supplement. 40-44.
  9. Davis, M. and Lo, V. (2001) Infectious Default. Quantitative Finance, 1, 382-386. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/713665832
  10. Dellacherie, C. (1972) Capacities et Processus Stochastique. Springer-Verlag, Brelin, Heidelberg, New York.
  11. Elliott, R.J. and Kopp, P.E. (1999) Mathematics of Financial Market. Springer-Verlag, Brelin, Heidelberg, New York.
  12. Elliott, R.J. (1982) Stochastic Calculus and Applications. Springer-Verlag, Brelin, Heidelberg, New York.
  13. Hull, J. and White, A. (1995) Valuing Credit Default Swaps II: Modeling Default Correlations. Journal of Derivatives, 8, 12-21. http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/jod.2001.319153
  14. Kao, D.L. (2000) Estimating and Pricing Credit Risk: An Overview. Financial Analysts Journal, 56, 50-66. http://dx.doi.org/10.2469/faj.v56.n4.2373
  15. Nwozo, C.R. and Fadugba, S.E. (2012) Some Numerical Methods for Options Valuation. Communications in Mathematical Finance, 1, 51-74.
  16. Titman, S. and Torous, W. (1989) Valuing Commercial Mortgages: An Empirical Investigation of the Contingent Claims Approach to Pricing Risky Debt. Journal of Finance, 44, 345-373. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2328594
  17. Weiss, L.A. (1999) Bankrupty Resolution: Direct Costs and Violations of Priority of Claims. Journal of Financial Economics, 27, 251-272.
  18. Yang, L. and Zhiqiang, H. (2013) Monte Carlo Method for High-Tech Enterprise IPO Market Timing: Empirical Study Based on American Real Option Approach. International Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, 44, 188-195.
  19. Wang, Z.G., Ou, Y.G. and Cai, B.G. (2012) Option Pricing Formula for Stock Model. International Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, 27, 49-55.
  20. Madan, D.B. and Unal, H. (1998) Pricing the Risks of Default. Review of Derivatives Research, 2, 121-160. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF01531333