Theoretical Economics Letters
Vol.2 No.2(2012), Article ID:19329,5 pages DOI:10.4236/tel.2012.22040

Note on a Continuum Multi-Country and International Trade

Keita Kamei

Graduate School of Economics, Kyoto University, Kyoto, Japan

Email: Keita.Kamei@gmail.com

Received February 21, 2012; revised March 27, 2012; accepted April 3, 2012

Keywords: Multi-Country Trade; Ricardian Model

ABSTRACT

We provide an analytical solution for the continuum multi-country two-sector Ricardian model of Yanagawa (1996) [1], and obtain additional results that are not observed in the standard two-country two-good Ricardian model. Increases in productivity in each sector results in an increase in the number of countries producing high technology goods and a decrease in the number of countries producing low technology goods.

1. Introduction

At present, economists primarily use the two-country model to analyze international trade. However, in the real world multiple countries simultaneously trade goods and services among themselves. Hence, the use of a multicountry model is more realistic for economic analysis.

Nevertheless, the multi-country model is not used as frequently as the two-country model, primarily because multi-country analysis is very complicated and, therefore, difficult to apply1. One of the simplest multi-country models is by Yanagawa (1996) [1].

The model by Yanagawa (1996) [1] is based on the model by Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson (1977) [3] (the DFS model). Yanagawa (1996) [1] extended the DFS model, a two-country model with a continuum of goods, to a continuum multi-country two-good model, while retaining the simplicity of the DFS model. Therefore, the Yanagawa (1996) [1] model provides for a relatively simple approach to continuum multi-country analysis of international trade.

Regardless of its simplicity, the model by Yanagawa (1996) [1] has not attracted significant use in trade theory and application because it does not provide an analytical solution.

Our study rebuilds on the model of Yanagawa (1996) [1] and provides an analytical solution using a simple specification. We also reveal an interesting aspect of the model that is not observed in the standard two-country two-good Ricardian model: An increase in productivity in each sector results in an increase in the number of countries producing high technology goods and a decrease in the number of countries producing low technology goods.

2. The Model

This section explains the basic framework of our model. We suppose that an economy is composed of two sectors: low technology sector and high technology sector. Countries in the world continuously exist. In this economy, all goods are produced using only labor with constant returns to scale technology. The labor employed in sector of country is denoted by. The labor productivity in sector of country is, and the output of good in country is. Both the goods markets are competitive. Further, production function are, , and,.

Now, we assume that the countries of the world are organized in order of economic development from. We specify production technology as follows:

(1)

(2)

where and are the technological levels in each sector. The production function in each sector is an increasing function of. Hence, low index countries have absolute disadvantage in each sector as compared to high index countries.2

Figure 1 (Figure 2) show the x sector (y sector) productiveity of country, and it is an increasing function of. The productivity in each sector in country is one and the productivity in each sector in country is zero. Hence, the productivity in each country and represents the level of development based on the productivity of and. If the levels of technology a or b decrease (productivity increases), then the productivity of the countries and comes close to the productivity of country 3.

We assume that labor is full employment. Suppose that the total labor endowment is given by and is identical across countries. Then, in each country, the labor market clearing condition leads to. Suppose that the labor is perfectly mobile between the two sectors, but is immobile across countries. Accordingly, wage is identical in the two sectors. From the

Figure 1. Productivity in low technology sector (a > a').

Figure 2. Productivity in high technology sector (b > b').

profit functions and the zero-profit conditions, we obtain the following condition:

(3)

where denotes the price in sector under autarky. Equation (3) indicates that relative price is equal to relative productivity in country under autarky.

Next, let us formulate a consumer behavior. Suppose that the consumers obtain utility from x and y, and that all consumers in this economy share identical preferences. The utility maximization problem is given by

(4)

(5)

where denotes the consumption of good and represents the degree of consumer preference for the low technology good. The condition for the utility maximiztion is given by

(6)

Suppose that the relative productivity between x sector and y sector satisfies the following condition:

(7)

The larger the value of z, the higher the relative productivity between the two sectors. Therefore, this assumption implies that the order of comparative advantage in y is increasing in z. The production functions (1) and (2) satisfy the condition (7).

Analogous to the two-country Ricardian model, countries with relative productivity lower than the world relative price, , will specialize in the low technology sector. Countries with relative productivity higher than will specialize in the high technology sector.

Let us define as the country with the relative productivity equal to the world relative price. We call the country boundary country. Countries within the range specialize in the low technology sector, countries within the range specialize in the high technology sector.

All countries except the boundary country must specialize in the low technology goods (x) or the high technology goods (y). If the countries specialize in x sector, then, and if the countries specialize in y sector, then. Hence, the production functions x and y under free trade lead to, , and to,.

The relative productivity between x sector and y sector is as follows:

(8)

where we assume that.

Then, we obtain the following equation.

(9)

Equation (9) implies that the relative productivity of the boundary country equals the world relative price under free trade.

From the aggregate supply functions under free trade, we obtain each sector’s total output in the world:

(10)

(11)

We derive the world demand for good i. All countries are distributed within the range, and we aggregate the demand in each country to derive total output thoughout the world. Aggregate demands and

are given by and.

Using Equation (6), the utility maximization condition as follows:

(12)

3. Equilibrium

The market clearing conditions lead to and. Substituting the market cleaning conditions into Equation (12), we obtain the following equation:

(13)

If Equation (9) equals Equation (13), then the boundary country in equilibrium and the equilibrium world relative price are determined. The resultant expression is as follows:

(14)

From, is 4.

Figure 3 represents Equations (9) and (13), the boundary country in equilibrium, and the world relative price in equilibrium.

4. Discussion

This section analyzes how exogeneous technological progress in each sector (a decrease in or) changes the number of countries specializing in the low (or high) technology sector. The change in the boundary country is examined analytically.

Proposition 1. An increase in productivity in the low technology sector (a decrease in of sector x) increases the number of countries specializing in the high technology sector y.

Proof. See Appendix A.□

Proposition 2. An increase in productivity in the high technology sector (a decrease in of sector y) increases the number of countries specializing in the high technology sector y.

Proof. See Appendix B.□

Figure 4 graphically represents Proposition 1. If decreases, then the and curves rise. Hence, the equilibrium point moves from E to E’ and the number of countries that produce the high technology goods increases Furthermore, Figure 5 represents Proposition 2 graphically. If b decreases, then the and curves fall. The equilibrium point moves from E to E" and the number of countries that produce high technology production increases.

Let us confirm the above propositions using numerical calculations. We set the criteria parameters as and and examine a shift in the boundary country through technological progress (a decrease in a or b) and a change in the total production quantity in each sector. Table 1 summarizes the results of the numerical analysis.

An increase in productivity in each sector results in an

Figure 3. Relative labor productivity in each sector, relative optimal consumption rate, boundary country, and equilibrium relative price.

Figure 4. The case of an increase in productivity in the low technology sector (α decrease in a).

Figure 5. The case of an increase in productivity in the high technology sector (α decrease in b).

Table 1. Total quantity of low technology production and high technology production, and the boundary country index.

increase in the number of countries specializing in the high technology goods. First, we explain the case of an increase in productivity in the low technology sector. Such an increase results in higher real income of consumers and greater demand for high technology goods. Hence, a greater number of countries specialize in the high technology production. Second, we explain the case of an increase in productivity in the high technology sector. Countries specializing in the low technology sector are low index countries. Under the production function, productivity in countries specializing in the low technology sector is low compared with countries specializing in the high technology sector. Hence, following an increase in the productivity of the high technology sector, production efficiency in countries specializing in the low technology sector decreases, resulting in these countries stopping their low technology production and specializing in the high technology goods.

We compare the result of our model with that of the standard two-country two-good Ricardian model. Under the standard Ricardian model, a country that specializes in the low technology production can never specialize in the high technology production when productivity in the low technology sector is increasing. However, our result shows that an increase in productivity in the low technology sector increases the number of countries specializing in the high technology production.

5. Conclusion

We derived an analytical solution by rebuilding the Yanagawa (1996) [1] model. Our results show that an increase in productivity in each sector increases the number of countries that produce the high technology goods and decreases the number of countries producing the low technology goods. These results are not observed in the standard Ricardian model.

REFERENCES

  1. N. Yanagawa, “Economic Development in a World with Many Countries,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 49, No. 2, 1996, pp. 271-288. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(95)00062-3
  2. G. Becker, “A Note on Multi-Country Trade,” American Economic Review, Vol. 42, No. 4, 1952, pp. 558-568.
  3. R. Dornbusch, S. Fischer and P. Samuelson, “Comparative Advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods,” American Economic Review, Vol. 67, No. 5, 1977, pp. 823-839.
  4. H. Fadinger and P. Fleiss, “Trade and Sectoral Productivity,” Economic Journal, Vol. 121, No. 6, 2011, pp. 958- 989.

Appendix A

Proof of Proposition 1

Proof. We differentiate Equation (14) with respect to, resulting in the following expression:

(15)

Appendix B

Proof of Proposition 2

Proof. We differentiate Equation (14) with respect to, resulting in the following expression:

Here, we define. Hence, if

, then. We differentiate this with respect to, resulting in the following:

Therefore, is a monotonically decreasing function with respect to. Moreover,

Consequently,.

NOTES

1For example, see Becker (1952) [2].

2This assumption is based on the stylized fact that productivity in each sector in developed countries is higher than that in each sector in developing countries, as discussed in Fadinger and Fleiss (2011) [4]. Therefore, the specifications of Equations (1) and (2) are realistic.

3Note that if 0 < z < 1 and a > a', then. Hence, a decrease in a implies an increasein productivity in the low technology sector. The case of b is similar.

4Using Equation (14), we can derive welfare in each country and world output in each sector.